Referring to the challenges mentioned above, healthcare systems in industrialized countries have to find an appropriate trade-off between controlling expenditures within the regulated benefit basket and fostering innovation and ensuring access to new diagnosis and treatment options (Levaggi, 2014, p. 69).3 Employing drug price regulation is one of the standard approaches employed to meet that optimisation problem and is directly connected with elaborating some forms of a value for money measurement. One specific strategy is based on so-called value-based pricing.
2.1 Risk-sharing within a value-based regulation approach
Value-based pricing approaches are rooted within a legitimation of a price by its impact on a perceived or estimated value to the patient.4 Different strategies of value-based pricing on the macroeconomic level have been implemented. An incremental cost effectiveness ratio is used, for example, to give an appraisal for developing a price cap for pharmaceutical reimbursement in the United Kingdom (UK), as a Beveridge-type country (OECD, 2010, p. 166). Bismarckian-type countries, such as Germany, believe in the idea that decentralized regulated competition is an additional means for elaborating “value for money”, fostering variations in preference and willingness to pay. However, regardless of the macroeconomic approaches chosen by different countries, fostering the development of new drugs while bearing in mind limited resources is the definite optimisation problem which each healthcare system faces.
Against the background of rising costs for medical drugs and limits of established models for financing new drugs, we will focus in the following on risk-sharing agreements utilising value-based pricing which have been developed as one standardized approach to control pharmaceutical expenditures.
Risk-sharing agreements can be defined as
agreements concluded by payers and pharmaceutical companies to diminish the impact on the payer's budget of new and existing medicines brought about by either the uncertainty of the value of the medicine and/or the need to work within finite budgets. (Adamski et al., 2010)
According to the logic of risk-sharing agreements, pharmaceutical companies grant some kind of warranty for the value of a medical drug. The company and the payer both have different obligations depending on the occurrence of an agreed condition (Adamski et al., 2010; Renze-Westendorf, 2010, p. 206).
Participants of risk-sharing agreements acknowledge that there are uncertainties regarding developing and marketing a medical drug, i.e. risks regarding the clinical and economic performance in the real world. It is not clear whether the effectiveness of a medical drug in clinical reality, particularly at the time of its admission, reflects the efficacy shown in clinical trials (Antonanzas et al., 2011, p. 399, 2011, p. 399; Garrison et al., 2013, p. 704). These uncertainties are especially considerable for new, innovative and expensive drugs that only address small target populations. The reason for this is that clinical studies are small in such cases and, therefore, the accompanying evidence is sparse. Accordingly, there is an outcome uncertainty in terms of the patients’ response to treatment and how that will translate into health outcomes and resource utilisation, as well as a subgroup uncertainty, i.e. which patients of the heterogeneous population should and do get treated (Carlson et al., 2010, p. 188).
From the payer's point of view, these uncertainties are even more pronounced by the inherent characteristic of drugs as a post-launch “experience” good. Consequently, there is a specific risk of an ongoing asymmetry of information between the pharmaceutical company and different cost-payers considering the results of the implementation of the new drug, especially the number of prescriptions by doctors and the valuation of the beneficiaries. Controlling the expected profit margin in these cases is very complex for the pharmaceutical company from an ex ante perspective. If payers are additionally risk-averse, i.e. they have a greater fear of incorrectly paying than not paying for a cost-ineffective technology, they will insist on paying only for the (most) effective healthcare interventions within their limited budget (Towse and Garrison, 2010, p. 94).
Considering that assumption, pharmaceutical companies run the risk that the real-world value of a manufactured drug is underestimated. In the worst case, the payer refuses to adopt the drug at all (Garrison et al., 2013, p. 704). In addition, there may be high development costs and manufacturing overheads for a potentially curative or, at least, disease-modifying therapy that is only applicable to a small market and must be compensated by high list prices (Editorial, 2019, p. 697).
Pharmaceutical companies and cost-payers have different priorities regarding the payment because they have different information and views about the value of a new drug and the allocation of the accompanying risks. However, one potential shared interest is an objective assessment of benefits and costs. Obviously, such a value-oriented assessment is especially important for very expensive pharmaceuticals because there is a lot at stake for both sides: The pharmaceutical company wants its expenses for research and development to be compensated, while the payer needs to weigh the new drug against other therapies they may no longer be able to fund. In particular cases in which evidence is limited at the time of admission of the drug, for example, due to small studies for an orphan disease, it may be possible that the payer and manufacturer cannot align their expectations of remuneration and the company decides to drop out rather than to accept the price of the payer.
In order to avoid this situation, risk-sharing schemes enable the risk mentioned to be shared between payer and manufacturer by making the value of the drug, i.e. the price or remuneration, dependent on the value of the product, i.e. the future proven effectiveness in the real world (OECD, 2010, p. 170). Hereby, the payments to be made will be fixed ex ante and are contingent on information that will be collected ex post (Antonanzas et al., 2011, p. 400). Such value-based schemes may not only help to control pharmaceutical expenditures without negatively impacting the patient populations but also enable discounts without changing the high list price. This is relevant from the perspective of the pharmaceutical company, because the list price serves as an international comparison and changes may affect manufacturers’ global revenues (Carlson et al., 2010, p. 188; Towse and Garrison, 2010, pp. 95–96).
Risk-sharing agreements can be distinguished according to either financial/financial-based schemes or outcome/performance-based models (Adamski et al., 2010).
2.2 Financial-based risk-sharing agreements
Finance-based schemes do not usually take the patient outcome into account but concentrate more on keeping the expenditures within agreed limits (Adamski et al., 2010). Some examples of this risk-sharing approach are price volume agreements or budget impact schemes, according to which the unit price of a product is linked to the volumes sold. An increase of the volume of units results in a declining cost per unit. This is especially important when there is a possibility that the new medicine will be prescribed in a wider population than anticipated (Adamski et al., 2010; OECD, 2010, p. 170).
Another form of financial-based risk-sharing is patient access schemes, which seek to enhance the value of new drugs and improve the possibility of their funding. They involve either the use of a drug for free or with financial discounts for an agreed period of time, or they focus on controlling the financial impact from an individual patient's perspective in the form of price capping schemes. The latter are connected to a specific outcome element, for example, when the drugs are provided for free once patients have exceeded a specified number of units but need more to support a certain state of health. Such an arrangement prevents the payer from spending more than a fixed amount per patient (Adamski et al., 2010; OECD, 2010, p. 171).
2.3 Performance-based risk-sharing agreements
Performance-based risk-sharing schemes – also called performance-based-risk sharing agreements (PBRSA) – address the optimisation of definite healthcare expenditures as well. However, different from financed-based models, these schemes are dependent on the generation of evidence regarding the real-world impact of a given drug on patients’ health. The remuneration depends on the (real-world) effectiveness of the drug according to data collection subsequent to the admission of the drug. Remuneration is determined either directly by a pre-arranged rule or indirectly through an agreement regarding the option to renegotiate prices if a certain condition has been met (Adamski et al., 2010; Garrison et al., 2013, p. 705). The outcomes, which serve as a basis for the remuneration, may be defined either in terms of outcome-related benefits (e.g. clinical response) or cost-effectiveness (e.g. cost per quality-adjusted life year5), each at the individual patient level or the aggregated level of the whole population treated (OECD, 2010, p. 172).
There are different types of PBRSA: Using outcome guarantees, the treatment costs for patients not reaching a predetermined response are (fully or partially) paid back by the manufacturer. One prominent example which has been discussed in this regard is the coverage for CAR T-cells (Jørgensen et al., 2020). Another type of PBRSA involves coverage with evidence development. This approach means that there is access to a new drug while evidence is generated within a given period of time. However, reimbursement may change during the course of this time depending on the findings regarding predetermined health outcomes. Finally, PBRSA involving conditional treatment continuation means that reimbursement only takes place if patients achieve a previously defined level of response (Gonçalves et al., 2018).
Implementing a successful PBRSA needs some serious preliminary considerations. In particular, the costs of generating additional evidence or information on treatment response must be weighed against the benefits that better resource allocation decisions bring, which is basically an investment decision. All parties have to decide beforehand whether a PBRSA is acceptable to them in the given situation and with the given risk. In addition, there is the need for consideration regarding how the PBRSA should be implemented and evaluated to be successful. Among the many questions which must be answered are the choice of the appropriate study design and outcome parameters, consideration about who will measure these parameters and in which time frame, what the reimbursement modalities will look like and a lot more (Garrison et al., 2013, p. 709). These questions are raised by different interests that have to be embedded within the PBRSA.
The PBRSA approach seems appropriate if there is a significant uncertainty regarding the effectiveness of a given drug, while, at the same time, there is the desire to provide patients with access to its potential benefit. Therefore, it is especially interesting for funding new and innovative medicines such as orphan drugs and gene therapies. In contrast to this, finance-based schemes are more useful for generics, where one assumes that the outcome is already known and does not need to be considered (Carlson et al., 2010, p. 180; Gonçalves et al., 2018).
A second interesting feature of PBRSAs is that there is the possibility of generating additional evidence. The latter is a desirable public good since it is not only valuable regarding the certain drug to be assessed, but it also offers insights into the respective disease itself and, therefore, enables a general improvement of patient care.
Given the preceding analysis, PBRSAs seem potentially desirable from an ethical and societal perspective. However, it is necessary to analyse the advantages and barriers of a PBRASA to determine its value and possible limitations in practice (Garrison et al., 2013, pp. 717–718). The multiple sclerosis (MS) risk-sharing scheme, which has been established in the UK, is an illustrative example to learn about a PBRSA in practice and its associated strengths and weaknesses. This case example will be described and, subsequently, the benefits and problems with implementation of PBRSAs in practice will be discussed in the following.