U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

NCBI Bookshelf. A service of the National Library of Medicine, National Institutes of Health.

Jamison DT, Gelband H, Horton S, et al., editors. Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty. 3rd edition. Washington (DC): The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank; 2017 Nov 27. doi: 10.1596/978-1-4648-0527-1_ch1

Cover of Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty

Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty. 3rd edition.

Show details

Chapter 1Universal Health Coverage and Intersectoral Action for Health

, , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , , and .

Image WB.978-1-4648-0527-1.common1

Corresponding author: Dean T. Jamison, University of California, San Francisco, California, United States; ude.wu@nosimajd.

INTRODUCING DISEASE CONTROL PRIORITIES, THIRD EDITION

In 1993, the World Bank published Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries (DCP1), an attempt to systematically assess value for money (cost-effectiveness) of interventions that would address the major sources of disease burden in low- and middle-income countries (LMICs) (Jamison and others 1993). A major motivation for DCP1 was to identify reasonable responses in highly resource-constrained environments to the growing burden of noncommunicable diseases (NCDs) and of human immunodeficiency virus/acquired immune deficiency syndrome (HIV/AIDS) in LMICs. The World Bank had highlighted the already substantial NCD problem in country studies for Malaysia (Harlan, Harlan, and Oii 1984), for China (Jamison and others 1984), and in a New England Journal of Medicine Shattuck Lecture (Evans, Hall, and Warford 1981). Mexican scholars (Bobadilla and others 1993; Frenk and others 1989) pointed to the rapid growth of NCDs in Mexico and introduced the concept of a protracted epidemiological transition involving a dual burden of NCDs combined with significant lingering problems of infectious disease. The dual burden paradigm remains valid to this day. The World Bank’s first (and so far only) World Development Report (1993) dealing with health drew heavily on findings from DCP1 to conclude that a number of specific interventions against NCDs (including tobacco control and multidrug secondary prevention of vascular disease) were attractive even in environments where substantial burdens of infection and insufficient dietary intake remained policy priorities (World Bank 1993).

Disease Control Priorities, second edition (DCP2), published in 2006, updated and extended DCP1 most notably by explicit consideration of implications for health systems of expanded coverage of high-priority interventions (Jamison and others 2006). One important link to health systems was through examination of selected platforms for delivering logistically related interventions that might address quite heterogeneous sets of problems. Platforms examined included the district hospital as a whole, the surgical and emergency room platforms within the district hospital, and school-based platforms for delivering a range of services. Platforms often provide a more natural unit for investment—and for estimating costs—than do individual interventions. Analysis of the costs of providing platforms—and of the health improvements they can generate in a given epidemiological environment—can thus help guide health system investments and development. Both Disease Control Priorities, third edition (DCP3), and the World Health Organization’s (WHO) major investment case for health (Stenberg and others 2017) continue to utilize platforms and their costs as important organizing concepts.

This chapter conveys the main findings of DCP3, and in particular its conclusions concerning intersectoral policy priorities and essential universal health coverage (EUHC). Like its two predecessors, DCP3’s broad aim is to assist decision makers in allocating often tightly constrained budgets so that health system objectives are maximally achieved. Beyond informing policy discourse, the granularity of analysis reported in DCP3’s nine volumes is intended to serve officials within ministries at the implementation level. Beginning with DCP3 volume 1 on Essential Surgery, DCP3’s first eight volumes (and related overviews of six of them in The Lancet) appeared between 2015 and 2017. This final volume contains cross-cutting and synthesizing chapters. Box 1.1 lists DCP3’s nine volumes and their editors.

Box Icon

Box 1.1

DCP3’s Nine Volumes.

DCP3 differs importantly from DCP1 and DCP2 in terms of its multivolume format, in terms of extending and consolidating the concept of platforms, and in terms of explicit consideration of a broad range of intersectoral and fiscal policies for health. Figure 1.1 illustrates the division of DCP3’s analyses between intersectoral policies and health sector policies and shows examples of the risk factors and conditions that the policies address. Importantly, the DCP3 structure views the role of intersectoral action to be reduction of behavioral and environmental risks, which themselves affect the level of physiological risks and health outcomes directly. The health sector’s role in reducing behavioral and environmental risk is viewed as modest—rather the health sector’s main role is in reducing (some of) the physiological risk factors and reducing the duration and severity of health conditions and their sequelae. Appropriate health sector policies also offer the potential for reducing health-related financial risks in a population.

Figure 1.1. Policies for Health.

Figure 1.1

Policies for Health.

DCP3 has four major objectives that go beyond previous editions. The first is to address explicitly the financial risk protection and poverty reduction objective of health systems, as well as other objectives such as provision of contraception, reduction in stillbirths, and palliative care or enhancement of the physical and cognitive development of children. Standard health metrics such as the quality-adjusted life year (QALY) and disability-adjusted life year (DALY) fail to encompass these other objectives of health systems, and DCP3 has endeavored to be explicit about them and their importance. The second extension lies in systematic attention to the intersectoral determinants of health.

The third major way that DCP3 goes beyond previous editions lies in organizing interventions into 21 essential packages reflecting professional communities. Table 1.1 lists DCP3’s 21 packages. DCP3 defines a concept of EUHC in the health systems components of the essential 21 packages. DCP3 further identifies a subset of EUHC, the highest-priority package (HPP), that can potentially be afforded by low-income countries (LICs) and that offers the most potential achievement (given limited resources) of health, financial protection, and other objectives. Finally, DCP3 provides estimates for low- and lower-middle-income countries of incremental and total costs in 2030 for both EUHC and HPP and of the magnitude of their impact on mortality. In addition to these new elements, DCP3 updates the efforts of DCP1 and DCP2 to assemble and interpret the literature on economic evaluation of health interventions.

Table 1.1. DCP3’s Clusters of Essential Packages.

Table 1.1

DCP3’s Clusters of Essential Packages.

This chapter introduces the substantive topics addressed by DCP3 and relays our main conclusions. Before turning to that, we briefly describe the context in which DCP3’s analyses have been undertaken.

CONTEXT

Five considerations set the context for DCP3: (a) the 20th-century revolution in human health, (b) the scientific underpinnings of that revolution, (c) the high estimated returns to (carefully chosen) health investments, and (d) the increasing implementation of universal health coverage (UHC) as a practical goal for domestic finance of health systems. Skolnik (2016) provides further discussion of these four issues. A fifth consideration concerns evolution in the thinking about the international dimension of health finance—development assistance for health broadly defined.

Chile exemplifies the two key elements of the 20th-century revolution in human health. One is the sheer magnitude of improvement. As recently as 1910, Chilean life expectancy fell below 32 years. By 2012, life expectancy exceeded 78 years. Second, time has narrowed cross-country differences. In 1910, world leaders (such as Australia and New Zealand) achieved life expectancies almost 30 years greater than Chile, but by 2010 that gap had narrowed to around 4 years. The magnitude of Chile’s success has been unusual, but the broad story it conveys is not. That said, Sub-Saharan Africa now lags 20 years behind global life expectancy of 72 years, and countries in other regions (and regions within large countries) remain similarly disadvantaged. DCP3’s main purpose is to provide information to help close those gaps.

Income growth in the past century and past decades has contributed to increased life expectancy as has, to a somewhat greater extent, improvements in education levels (Pradhan and others 2017). Most improvements, however, have resulted from an ever-expanding menu of drugs, diagnostics, vaccines, and knowledge (Jamison, Jha, and others 2013). Nurturing continuation of the scientific investment therefore remains a policy priority, as was extensively discussed in DCP2 (Bloom and others 2006; Mahmoud and others 2006; Meltzer 2006; Weatherall and others 2006). DCP3 has devoted less attention to research and development (R&D) than did DCP2—in part because of the coverage there. While R&D is discussed in several places (for example, Bundy and others 2017; Trimble and others 2015), a careful mining of DCP3 for its implications for R&D remains to be done.

Valuation of mortality decline (or health change more generally) is excluded from the global system of national income and product accounts. Economists have nonetheless expended substantial effort tracing the effect of health improvements on household and national income and in assessing the value of the small reductions in mortality risk that have occurred year by year. Global Health 2035 (GH2035), the report of the Lancet Commission on Investing in Health (Jamison, Summers, and others 2013), reviewed and extended the literature on the value of health improvements. That literature points to high returns indeed. The Copenhagen Consensus, a project that comparatively assesses returns across all major development sectors, has likewise found high returns: its 2012 assessment found that 9 of the 15 highest return investments were health-related, including all of the top 5 (Kydland and others 2013).

As national incomes rise, countries typically increase the percentage of national income devoted to health. Equally significantly, they increase the proportion of health expenditures that are prepaid, usually through public or publicly mandated finance. WHO’s leadership in advancing a global UHC agenda has accelerated this underlying movement of political systems toward UHC. Dr. Tedros Ghebreyesus, WHO’s new Director-General, has reaffirmed the WHO commitment to UHC and to the use of evidence and data in support of achieving that goal (Ghebreyesus 2017). GH2035 advocated variants on a pathway toward UHC, “progressive universalism,” that emphasized two initial priorities for action: (a) universal coverage of publicly financed interventions and (b) reductions of user payments at the point of service to very low levels (Jamison, Summers, and others 2013). With inevitable constraints on public budgets, these two priorities point to the need for initial selectivity in the range of interventions to be publicly financed, the so-called benefits package. Many considerations will influence national choices of how benefits packages will evolve over time and on the appropriate pathways to universalism. Hence, the importance of maintaining the focus on the highest priority health investments as DCP3 is intended to facilitate.

With substantial income growth in most LMICs and an increasing number of countries committed to public finance of UHC, the role of development assistance is being reexamined (Bendavid and others 2018; Jamison, Summers, and others 2013). As the World Bank and others have long argued, finance ministers will often reduce domestic allocations to sectors receiving substantial foreign aid. The challenge to those concerned with aid effectiveness thus becomes one of identifying and supporting important activities that national finance ministries are likely to underfinance (such as R&D, pandemic preparedness, and control of antimicrobial resistance). A recent assessment found that support for these international functions already constitutes more than 20 percent of development assistance broadly defined; the authors make the case that percentage should steadily increase over time (Schäferhoff and others 2015). This view of development assistance has clear implications for the construction of model benefits packages for domestic finance; other things being equal, domestic finance needs to emphasize services having minimal international externalities.

PACKAGES, PLATFORMS, AND POLICIES

DCP3 defines packages of interventions as conceptually related interventions—for example, those dealing with cardiovascular disease or reproductive health or surgery. An objective of each DCP3 volume was to define one or more essential packages and the interventions in that package that might be acquired at an early stage on the pathway to UHC. The essential packages comprise interventions that provide value for money, are implementable, and address substantial needs.

Platforms are defined as logistically related delivery channels. DCP3 groups EUHC interventions within packages that can be delivered on different types of platforms. The temporal character of interventions is critical for health system development. Patients requiring nonurgent but substantial intervention—repair of cleft lips and palates is an example—can be accumulated over space and time, enabling efficiencies of high volume in service delivery. Urgent interventions, which include a large fraction of essential surgical interventions, are ideally available 24/7 close to where patients live—with important implications for dispersal of relevant platforms and integration of different services. Nonurgent but continuing interventions to address chronic conditions (for example, secondary prevention of vascular disease or antiretroviral therapy for HIV–positive individuals) provide a major and quite distinct challenge. One new product of DCP3 has been to explicitly categorize all essential interventions into one of these three temporal categories and to draw relevant lessons, including concerning cost, for health systems.

In total, 71 distinct and important intersectoral policies for reducing behavioral and environmental risk were identified, and 29 of those were identified as candidates for early implementation. In addition to intersectoral policies, DCP3 reviews policies that affect the uptake of health sector interventions (such as conditional cash transfers) and the quality with which they are delivered (Peabody and others 2018).

METHODS

DCP3’s authors have thoroughly updated findings from DCP2 on costs, effectiveness, and cost-effectiveness. The literature provides much of specific interest, but formulation of policy, when informed by evidence at all, requires expert judgment to fill extensive gaps in the literature. The first subsection of this section discusses DCP3’s approach. The second and third subsections discuss methods of economic evaluation and DCP3’s extension of standard methods to include analysis of the financial protection objectives of health systems. The final subsection discusses the process of formulation of DCP3’s packages.

Use of Evidence

Using research (or other) evidence to guide policy is most simply done when randomized controlled trials of the relevant intervention (or mix of interventions) have been undertaken on the population of interest in the appropriate ecological setting. Even in high-income countries, such strong evidence is rarely available. In lower-income environments, the problem of the quality of evidence is compounded. As always, evidence must be used to help decision makers (a) avoid adopting interventions that don’t work in a given context and (b) avoid rejecting those that do. Box 1.2 discusses the DCP3 thinking on this issue.

Box Icon

Box 1.2

Evidence for Policy: From Research Findings to Policy Parameters.

Economic Evaluation

The methods and findings of DCP3’s approaches to economic evaluation appear in three separate chapters of this volume: one on cost-effectiveness, one on benefit-cost analysis, and one on extended cost-effectiveness analysis (Horton 2018; Chang, Horton, and Jamison 2018; Verguet and Jamison 2018). Table 1.2 provides a high-level overview. Several of the entries in that table—covering value for money, dashboards, and extended cost-effectiveness analysis—point to the desirability of multicriteria decision analysis of the sort explored by Youngkong (2012) and others.

Table 1.2. Economic Evaluation Methods.

Table 1.2

Economic Evaluation Methods.

The bottom row of table 1.2 takes the multioutcome extended cost-effectiveness analysis (ECEA) approach one step further to discussion of the “dashboard” DCP3 uses to help inform and structure setting priories. This health dashboard concept is a natural extension of the dashboard approach that Stigliz, Sen, and Fitoussi (2010) propose to go beyond gross domestic product (GDP) as a macroeconomic indicator. The health dashboard is likewise a natural step beyond use of cost-effectiveness league tables in constructing health benefit packages, an approach consistent with that of Glassman, Giedion, and Smith (2017).

Protecting against Financial Risk

In populations lacking access to health insurance or prepaid care, medical expenses that are high relative to income can be impoverishing (figure 1.2 illustrates mechanisms). Where incomes are low, seemingly inexpensive medical procedures can be catastrophic. WHO’s World Health Report 2010 documented the (very substantial) magnitude of medical impoverishment globally and pointed to the value of universal health coverage for addressing both the health and the financial protection needs of populations (WHO 2010). Most of the literature on medical impoverishment fails to identify the medical conditions responsible. Essue and others (2018) point to where specific causes of medical impoverishment information are known, an obviously central point for construction of benefits packages.

Figure 1.2. Financial Risk Protection.

Figure 1.2

Financial Risk Protection.

Although multiple studies document the overall magnitude of medical impoverishment, most economic evaluations of health interventions and their finance (including those in DCP1 and DCP2) have failed to address the important question of efficiency in the purchase of financial protection. In work undertaken for DCP3, an approach was developed—ECEA—to explicitly include financial protection and equity in economic evaluation of health interventions. Smith (2013) has developed an approach that addresses the same concern from a different perspective. ECEA is the approach that DCP3 used to address issues of both reduction in financial risk and distribution across income groups of financial as well as health outcomes resulting from policies, such as public finance, to increase intervention uptake. ECEA has been used to evaluate tobacco taxation and regulatory policies (Verguet and Jamison 2018). An important implication of the ECEA evaluations of tobacco taxation in China and in Lebanon was that such taxation, when the full range of consequences is considered, is progressive in terms of health outcomes and unlikely to be regressive in terms of financial outcomes (Salti, Brouwer, and Verguet 2016; Verguet and others 2015). A 13-country ECEA of tobacco taxation found results similar to those from China and Lebanon (Jha and Global Tobacco Economics Consortium 2017).

The tobacco ECEAs suggest a more general point about government policies to provide populations with protection against financial risk. Policy can operate either upstream or downstream. Upstream provision of financial risk protection (FRP) attenuates the need for costly medical intervention. Upstream measures include prevention, early treatment, and investment in improved medical technologies (see Lakdawalla, Malani, and Reif 2017). Most health systems emphasize downstream measures through payment for expensive procedures in the hospital. Downstream measures will always be needed. That said, resource constraints will sharply limit public finance of downstream financial protection; provision only of downstream measures perverts incentives in the obvious way and in many (but not all) cases upstream measures more efficiently purchase FRP given budget constraints.

Construction of Packages

Editors of DCP3 volumes and authors of specific chapters in volume 9—on rehabilitation (Mills and others 2018), on pathology (Fleming and others 2018), on palliative care (Krakauer and others 2018) and on pandemic preparedness (Madhav and others 2018)—constructed the 21 essential packages listed in table 1.1. The series editors and authors of this paper then consolidated those policies and formats into a common level of aggregation and a common structure (for example, screening was not considered an intervention by itself but only in conjunction with the indicated response). This generated a set of harmonized essential packages. The originals appear as an annex to this chapter, and chapters 2 and 3 provide a full discussion of methods. Several interventions appear in more than one package as the final lists of 71 intersectoral policies, and 218 EUHC interventions remove this duplication. A consequence is that the cost of EUHC is less than the sum of the costs of the packages within it.

INTERSECTORAL POLICIES FOR HEALTH

Eleven of DCP3’s 21 packages contain a total of 71 intersectoral policies. These policies fall into four broad categories: taxes and subsidies (15 of 71), regulations and related enforcement mechanisms (38 of 71), built environment (11 of 71), and information (7 of 71). These policies are designed to reduce the population level of behavioral and environmental risk factors—tobacco and alcohol use, air pollution, micronutrient deficiencies in the diet, unsafe sexual behavior, excessive sugar consumption, and others (figure 1.1). Watkins, Nugent, and others (2018) provide a thorough overview of DCP3’s findings on intersectoral policy. Here we highlight several of DCP3’s points:

First, at initially low levels of income, the levels of many risk factors rise with income, creating headwinds against which health sector policy must proceed. These rises are at least potentially countered by sound policy. We identify 29 of 71 intersectoral policies to be well worth considering for early adoption.

Second, for important categories of risk, such as pollution and transport risks, there are multiple sources of the risk, each of which is addressed through different modalities. Rather than a clear set of “first priorities,” there are multiple country- or site-specific actions to be taken. Perhaps the single most important point to note is that the success of many high-income countries in reducing these risks to very low levels points to the great potential that these multiple policies can have for dealing, in particular, with air pollution and road traffic injuries.

A third point of importance is that fiscal policies—finance ministry policies—are likely of key significance. Discussion of these policies has most prominently involved taxes on tobacco, alcohol, and sugar-sweetened beverages. But the possibilities for taxation are broader: sugar production and imports, fossil fuels (or carbon), and industrial or vehicle emissions. Also of importance is reducing expensive subsidies that now exist on fossil fuels and often on unhealthy food production or unhealthy child dietary supplements. While health improvement may be only one of several objectives for lowering subsidies, it is an important one. The literature on the health potential for removing subsidies remains limited. But the sheer magnitude of some of these subsidies, as the International Monetary Fund has stressed, points to the value of careful further analysis. In all likelihood, a country’s finance ministry is the most important ministry (after health) for improving population health. And many—not all—of the measures it can take can enhance public sector revenue.

ESSENTIAL UNIVERSAL HEALTH COVERAGE

The heart of DCP3 consisted of reviewing available evidence on health sector interventions’ costs, effectiveness, ability to be implemented, and capacity to deliver significant outcomes. DCP3’s nine volumes provide granular overviews of this evidence, overviews directed to the implementation community as well as to the policy community. Chapter 3 of volume 9 provides an integrative overview (Watkins, Jamison, and others 2018).

Figure 1.3 provides a schema of how DCP3 defines EUHC. Beyond EUHC is the full range of available, efficacious health sector interventions, or UHC. While no country publicly finances all interventions, many high-income countries come close and can reasonably be described as having achieved UHC. Short of EUHC is what DCP3 labels the HPP. Individual countries’ highest priorities will differ from our model list for multiple reasons. That said, the HPP is intended to provide a useful starting point for national or subnational assessments. As with EUHC, DCP3 provides estimates for the cost and effects of EUHC. GH2035 (Jamison, Summers, and others 2013) pointed to the possibility of a “grand convergence,” across most countries, in our lifetimes, in levels of under-age-five mortality and major infections. Figure 1.3 illustrates grand convergence in the DCP3 structure. The two following subsections provide our estimates of the costs and mortality-reducing consequences of EUHC.

Figure 1.3. Essential Universal Health Coverage and Highest-Priority Packages.

Figure 1.3

Essential Universal Health Coverage and Highest-Priority Packages.

Costs

We generated two estimates of costs for the health system component of each of DCP3’s 21 packages. The first was an estimate of how much additional funding it would take—in the 2015 cost and demographic environment—to implement each package to the extent judged feasible. The packages were designed so that for most cases, “full” implementation, defined as 80 percent effective coverage, was judged feasible by 2030. The second estimate of cost was of total cost for the package, defined as incremental cost plus the amount already (in 2015) being spent on the intervention. These costs were estimated both for LICs and for lower-middle-income countries. Some interventions were included in several packages, which was a natural outcome of a package formulation process that delineated packages as areas of concern to specific professional communities, such as surgeons or reproductive health specialists. Eliminating this duplication resulted in 218 distinct EUHC interventions. This implies that the sum of the package costs will exceed the cost of providing all packages. The subset of EUHC that was judged by explicit criteria to be highest priority (the HPP) was costed in the same way as for EUHC. All these costs are the estimated costs associated with expanding coverage in the 2015 environment, an environment for which we have substantial, if incomplete, information without making assumptions about the evolution of costs and epidemiology over time. Costs should be interpreted as long-term steady state costs, that is, costs that include (a) training of staff to replace retirements and (b) investment to counter depreciation of equipment and facilities.

Table 1.3 reports the calculated expenditure increases required above baseline and expresses those numbers as a percentage of gross national income (GNI). (Chapter 3, volume 9, of DCP3 reports costs by package.) We consider it reasonable to think of the costs in 2030 of EUHC and the HPP in these percentage terms (as well as in numbers of dollars). Only a small fraction of reasonably anticipated economic growth in most countries would cover the incremental costs of EUHC, although achieving the increased percentage of gross national income required would require substantial reallocation of public sector priorities (Jamison, Summers, and others 2013). In principle, projections could be made of changes in both the tradable and nontradable components of cost, of the responsiveness of costs to demography (and in particular to fertility decline), and on whether improved transport and other infrastructure might reduce our estimates of the cost of expanding coverage to ever-more difficult-to-reach parts of the population. In a country-specific context, this might well be worthwhile. But for purposes of reasonable overall cost estimates we judge that adding these layers of assumption would add little or nothing to the information content of table 1.3.

Table 1.3. Total and Incremental Annual Costs of Essential UHC and the Highest Priority Package, 2015 (in 2012 US$).

Table 1.3

Total and Incremental Annual Costs of Essential UHC and the Highest Priority Package, 2015 (in 2012 US$).

Table 1.4 presents our cost assessments divided along two other relevant dimensions. Panel a provides estimates of the costs associated with each platform, and about half of our calculated costs occur at the health center level. For EUHC, another 15 to 25 percent each of incremental expenditures would go to the first-level hospital and to the community level. Panel b reports intervention cost estimates by degree of urgency. The health systems implications for increasing intervention coverage differ markedly by urgency. Continuing interventions require appropriate community capacity for delivery. Examples include antiretroviral therapy or antihypertensive therapy. A full half of incremental costs are needed to finance continuing, very long-term intervention. Urgent interventions—for example, for trauma or obstructed labor—require that first-level hospitals be accessible quickly (Reynolds and others 2018). About one-quarter to one-third of incremental costs are required to provide this capacity. Nonurgent (but potentially important) interventions (for example, cataract extraction) allow patients to be accumulated over space and time with concomitant potential for efficiency and quality resulting from high volume.

Table 1.4. Incremental Costs of the HPP and EUHC by Platform and by Intervention Urgency, Percent.

Table 1.4

Incremental Costs of the HPP and EUHC by Platform and by Intervention Urgency, Percent.

Mortality Reduction from Essential UHC

DCP3 generated estimates of mortality in 2015, as well as estimates for a “counterfactual 2015” and of how many fewer deaths would have occurred following implementation of EUHC and the HPP. This analysis thus provides a reasoned estimate of the costs and consequences of using—in the 2015 demographic context—today’s medical and public health technology as fully as reasonably possible (as well as associated cost-effectiveness estimates). This subsection discusses estimates of mortality reduction.

Norheim and others (2015) developed a structure—40x30—for thinking about mortality reduction goals for the Sustainable Development Goal (SDG) period. Their starting point was the United Nations Population Division’s (UNPD) projected age distribution of population in 2030 and an age distribution of deaths generated from that age distribution of population and age-specific mortality rates from 2010. The overall 40x30 goal was, then, to reduce the calculated number of premature deaths by 40 percent, where premature is defined as under age 70 years. Subgoals were to reduce under-age-five and major infectious disease deaths by two-thirds and NCD and injury deaths by one-third.

Our approach in DCP3 followed the approach of Norheim and others (2015) in broad terms but inserts into it our “counterfactual 2015” analysis. We start with a baseline age distribution of deaths by age and (broad) cause generated from the UNPD’s projected 2030 age distribution of population and age combined with cause-specific death rates from 2015 (Mathers and others 2018). We then estimate the effect of EUHC (and HPP) on mortality by assuming that the underlying intervention packages are implemented over the 15 years from 2015 to 2030. (The packages were designed to make this assumption reasonable.) The age- and cause-specific mortality rates from counterfactual 2015 were then applied to the UNPD 2030 age distributions to give the age distributions of death by cause estimated to result from implementation of EUHC.

These calculations enable comparison of the EUHC mortality profile to an explicit counterfactual baseline. Table 1.5 shows these comparisons for EUHC and for the HPP. What we can see from this comparison is that full implementation of the HPP could achieve about half of the 40x30 goal. Full implementation of EUHC could achieve about two-thirds of the 40x30 goal. In a sensitivity analysis, Watkins, Norheim, and others (2018) demonstrate that higher levels of coverage (on the order of 95 percent) and more optimistic assumptions about the quality and efficiency of intervention delivery could acheive the 40x30 goal in lower-middle-income countries and exceed it by about 20 percent in low-income countries. If we were to assume that both tools and implementation capacity improve over the period to 2030—Global Health 2035 (Jamison, Summers, and others 2013) made an assumption of a 2 percent rate of technical progress in one of their scenarios—then the reduction in deaths from EUHC could be more substantial than shown in this table. Such progress is certainly possible, but may be unlikely. Likewise there could be more than anticipated reduction in behavioral and environmental risk. Our model is estimating what is technically and economically feasible given today’s tools. The results are indeed substantial—and are viable options for decision makers. But required resources are substantial, and at realistic (that is, 80 percent) coverage levels the goals are incompletely met. The actual decision to commit resources remains, of course, in the hands of national authorities.

Table 1.5. Implementation of DCP3’s Essential Packages: Estimated Reduction in Premature Deaths in 2030 (in Millions).

Table 1.5

Implementation of DCP3’s Essential Packages: Estimated Reduction in Premature Deaths in 2030 (in Millions).

CONCLUSIONS

DCP3 has been a large-scale enterprise involving multiple authors, editors, and institutions. The first volume appeared in 2015 and the last of the nine volumes is being published at the beginning of 2018. The volumes appear as serious discussion continues about quantifying and achieving SDGs, including SDG 3 for health.

DCP3’s analyses complement those of GH2035 and WHO’s recent assessments of the cost of attaining SDG 3 (Jamison, Summers, and others 2013; Stenberg and others 2017). Each of these analyses addresses somewhat different questions (table 1.6), but the broad results they convey are mutually supportive.

Table 1.6. Comparison of Global Health 2035, DCP3, and WHO 2017 Resource Estimates for Costs and Consequences of Large Scale Investment in Health Systems.

Table 1.6

Comparison of Global Health 2035, DCP3, and WHO 2017 Resource Estimates for Costs and Consequences of Large Scale Investment in Health Systems.

DCP3 reached six broad conclusions:

  1. DCP3 has found it useful to organize interventions into 21 essential packages that group the interventions relevant to particular professional communities. Each package can contain both intersectoral interventions and health system interventions. Specific findings from packages point to the attractiveness of widely available surgical capacity, the value of meeting unmet demand for contraception, the potential of a multipronged approach to air pollution and the importance of maintaining investment in child health and development far beyond the first 1000 days.
  2. Interventions were selected for packages by a systematic process using criteria of value for money, burden addressed, and implementation feasibility. Collectively, the selected interventions are defined to constitute “essential” universal health coverage or EUHC. A subset of 97 of these interventions, selected using more stringent criteria, are suggested as the highest-priority package or HPP, constituting an important first step on the path to EUHC. Five platforms—from population-based through the referral hospital—provide the delivery base for 218 health sector interventions. The specific interventions selected for the HPP and for EUHC and the definitions of platforms and packages are necessarily quite generic. Every country’s definitions and selections will differ from these and from each other’s. Nonetheless, we view DCP3’s selections as a potentially useful model—as a starting point for what are appropriately country-specific assessments.
  3. The costs estimated for the HPP and EUHC are substantial. The HPP is, however, affordable for LICs prepared to commit to rapid improvement in population health, and the EUHC is affordable for lower-middle-income countries. Many upper-middle-income countries have yet to achieve EUHC and they, too, might find that the EUHC interventions are a useful starting point for discussion.
  4. The goal of a 40 percent reduction in premature deaths by 2030 (Norheim and others 2015), 40x30, represents a goal for mortality reduction closely mirroring the quantitative content of SDG 3. Our calculations suggest that implementing EUHC or the HPP by 2030 will make substantial progress toward 40x30. Higher levels of coverage than we have assumed here would be required to reach 40x30, but this might be a realistic target for some early-adopter UHC countries.
  5. DCP3 has shown that it is possible to identify the main sources of health-related financial risk and impoverishment to estimate the value of risk reduction and to use ECEA to help achieve efficiency in purchase of risk reduction. Although DCP3 has made a beginning in applying these methods, much remains to be done.
  6. In addition to the aggregate conclusions of DCP3 just summarized, each volume provides rich detail on policy options and priorities. This granularity in the volumes makes them of use to the implementation level of government ministries as well as the policy level.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

We wish to acknowledge three institutions that have played key roles in DCP3. One is the World Bank, original home for the DCP series and accomplished publisher of its products. In the World Bank, Carlos Rossel and Mary Fisk oversaw the editing and publication of the series and served as critical champions for DCP3. The second is the Interacademy Medical Panel (IAMP) and its U.S. affiliate, the National Academy of Medicine (NAM). IAMP/NAM have organized a peer review process to cover chapters in the nine volumes; they established an Advisory Committee to the Editors (ACE), chaired by Anne Mills, that has been of enormous value. The Department of Global Health of the University of Washington has provided a congenial home for DCP for the past five years. We wish in particular to acknowledge the intellectual and practical support of the department’s two chairs during that period: King Homes and Judith Wasserheit. We also wish to acknowledge Brianne Adderley, Shamelle Richards, and Nazila Dabestani for their management, administrative, and research support to the production of DCP3.

ANNEX

The following annex to this chapter is available at http://www.dcp-3.org/DC.

  • Annex 1A: Essential Packages as They Appear in DCP3 Volumes 1 through 9

Note

World Bank Income Classifications as of July 2014 are as follows, based on estimates of gross national income (GNI) per capita for 2013:

  • Low-income countries (LICs) = US$1,045 or less
  • Middle-income countries (MICs) are subdivided:
    1. lower-middle-income = US$1,046 to US$4,125.
    2. upper-middle-income (UMICs) = US$4,126 to US$12,745.
  • High-income countries (HICs) = US$12,746 or more.

References

  1. Asaria M, Griffin S, Cookson R, Whyte S, Tappenden P. 2015. “Distributional Cost-Effectiveness Analysis of Health Care Programmes: A Methodological Case Study of the UK Bowel Cancer Screening Programme.” Health Economics 24 742–54. [PubMed: 24798212]
  2. Bates M A, Glennerster R. 2017. “The Generalizability Puzzle.” Stanford Social Innovation Review (summer). https://ssir​.org/articles​/entry/the_generalizability_puzzle.
  3. Bendavid E, Ottersen T, Liu P, Nugent R, Padian N., and others. 2018. “Development Assistance for Health.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212058]
  4. Bloom B R, Michaud C M, La Montagne J R, Simonsen L. 2006. “Priorities for Global Research and Development of Interventions.” In Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, second edition, edited by Jamison D T, Breman J G, Measham A R, Alleyne G, Claeson M, Evans D B, Jha P, Mills A, Musgrove P, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank and Oxford University Press. [PubMed: 21250309]
  5. Bobadilla J L, Frenk J, Lozano R, Frejka T, Stern C., and others. 1993. “The Epidemiologic Transition and Health Priorities.” In Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, first edition, edited by Jamison D T, Mosley W H, Measham A R, Bobadilla J L, editors. New York: Oxford University Press.
  6. Boyle C F, Levin C, Hatefi A, Madriz S, Santos N. 2015. “Achieving a ‘Grand Convergence’ in Global Health: Modeling the Technical Inputs, Costs, and Impacts from 2016 to 2030.” PLOS ONE 10 (10). [PMC free article: PMC4599920] [PubMed: 26452263]
  7. Bundy D A P, de Silva N, Horton S, Jamison D T, Patton G. C. eds. 2017. Child and Adolescent Health and Development, Disease Control Priorities . Volume 8 (third edition), edited by Jamison D T, Nugent R, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminaryan R, Mock C N, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank.
  8. Chang A, Horton S, Jamison D T. 2018. “Benefit-Cost Analysis in Disease Control Priorities, Third Edition.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212162]
  9. Essue B M, Laba T-L, Knaul F M, Chu A, Minh H V., and others. 2018. “Economic Burden of Chronic Ill Health and Injuries for Households in Low- and Middle-Income Countries.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212160]
  10. Evans J R, Hall K. L, Warford J. 1981. “Shattuck Lecture; Health Care in the Developing World: Problems of Scarcity and Choice.” New England Journal of Medicine 305 1117–27. [PubMed: 6793869]
  11. Fleming K, Naidoo M, Wilson M, Flanigan J, Horton S., and others. 2018. “High Quality Diagnosis: An Essential Pathology Package.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212155]
  12. Frenk J, Bobadilla J L, Sepúlveda J, Lopez-Cervantes M. 1989. “Health Transition in Middle-Income Countries: New Challenges for Health Care.” Health Policy and Planning 4 (1): 29–39.
  13. Glassman A, Giedion U, Smith P C. 2017. What’s In, What’s Out: Designing Benefits for Universal Health Coverage. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.
  14. Ghebreyesus T A. 2017. “All Roads Lead to Universal Health Coverage.” Commentary. The Lancet, July 17. [PubMed: 28728920]
  15. Harlan W R, Harlan L. C, Oii W L. 1984. “Changing Disease Patterns in Developing Countries: The Case of Malaysia.” In Health Information Systems, edited by Leaverton P, Massi L, editors. . New York: Praeger Scientific.
  16. Horton S E. 2018. “Cost-Effectiveness in Disease Control Priorities.”, Third Edition In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212058]
  17. Jamison D T. 2009. “Cost-Effectiveness Analysis: Concepts and Applications.” In Oxford Textbook of Public Health, The Methods of Public Health, (fifth edition). Volume 2 edited by Detels R, McEwen J, Beaglehole R, Tanaka H, editors. 767–82. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
  18. Jamison D T. 2015. “Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty.” The Lancet. Comment. doi: 10.1016/S0140-6736(15)60097-6. [PubMed: 30212058]
  19. Jamison D T, Alwan A, Mock C N, Nugent R, Watkins D A., and others. 2018. “Universal Health Coverage and Intersectoral Action for Health.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PMC free article: PMC5996988] [PubMed: 29179954]
  20. Jamison D T, Breman J G, Measham A R, Alleyne G, Claeson M, Evans D B, Jha P, Mills A, Musgrove P. eds. 2006. Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, second edition. Washington, DC: Oxford University Press and World Bank. [PubMed: 21250309]
  21. Jamison D T, Evans J R, King T, Porter I, Prescott N., and others. 1984. “China: The Health Sector.” Country Study. World Bank, Washington, DC.
  22. Jamison D T, Mosley W H, Measham A R, Bobadilla J L., eds. 1993. Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, first edition. New York: Oxford University Press.
  23. Jamison D T, Jha P, Malhotra V, Verguet St. 2013. “Human Health: The Twentieth-Century Transformation of Human Health—Its Magnitude and Value.” In How Much Have Global Problems Cost the World?: A Scorecard from 1900 to 2050, edited by Lomborg B, editor. , New York: Cambridge University Press.
  24. Jamison D T, Summers L H, Alleyne K J, Arrow G, Berkley S., and others. 2013. “Global Health 2035: A World Converging within a Generation.” The Lancet 382 (9908): 1898–955. [PubMed: 24309475]
  25. Jha P, Global Tobacco Economics Consortium. 2017. The Health, Poverty and Financial Consequences of a Large Tobacco Price Increase among 0.5 Billion Male Smokers in 13 Low- and Middle-Income Countries. Toronto: Centre for Global Health Research.
  26. Krakauer E, Ali Z, Arreola H, Bhadelia A, Connor S., and others. 2018. “Palliative Care.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212058]
  27. Kydland F E, Mundell R, Schelling T, Smith V, Stokey N. 2013. “Expert Panel Ranking” In Global Problems, Smart Solutions: Costs and Benefits, edited by Lomborg B, editor. 701–16. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
  28. Lakdawalla D, Malani A, Reif J. 2017. “The Insurance Value of Medical Innovation.” Journal of Public Economics 145 94–102.
  29. Madhav N, Oppenheim B, Gallivan M, Mulembakani P, Rubin E., and others. 2018. “Pandemics: Risks, Mitigation, and Costs.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank.
  30. Mahmoud A, Danzon P M, Barton J H, Mugerwa R D. 2006. “Product Development Priorities.” In Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, second edition, edited by Jamison D T, Breman J G, Measham A R, Alleyne G, Claeson M, Evans D B, Jha P, Mills A, Musgrove P, editors. . Washington, DC: Oxford University Press and World Bank. [PubMed: 21250309]
  31. Mathers C, Stevens G, Hogan D, Mahanani A, Ho J. 2018. “Global and Regional Causes of Death: Patterns and Trends, 2000–15.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212152]
  32. Meltzer D. 2006. “Economic Approaches to Valuing Global Health Research.” In Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, second edition, edited by Jamison D T, Breman J G, Measham A R, Alleyne G, Claeson M, Evans D B, Jha P, Mills A, Musgrove P, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank and Oxford University Press. [PubMed: 21250315]
  33. Mills J A, Marks E, Reynolds T, Cieza A. 2018. “Rehabilitation: Essential Along the Continuum of Care.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank.
  34. Norheim O F, Jha P, Admasu K, Godal T, Hum R H., and others. 2015. “Avoiding 40% of the Premature Deaths in Each Country, 2010–30: Review of National Mortality Trends to Help Quantify the UN Sustainable Development Goal for Health.” The Lancet 385 (9964): 239–52. [PubMed: 25242039]
  35. Ozler B. 2013. “Learn to Live without External Validity.” Development Impact (blog). World Bank, Washington, DC. https://blogs​.worldbank​.org/impactevaluations​/learn-live-without-external-validity.
  36. Peabody J, Shimkhada R, Adeyi O, Wang H, Broughton E., and others. 2018. “Quality of Care.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank.
  37. Pradhan E, Suzuki E M, Martínez S, Schäferhoff M., and others. 2017. “The Effects of Education Quantity and Quality on Child and Adult Mortality: Their Magnitude and Their Value.” In Disease Control Priorities, Child and Adolescent Health and Development (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Bundy D A P, de Silva N, Horton S E, Jamison D T, Patton G C, editors. . Washington, D.C.: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212146]
  38. Reynolds T, Sawe H, Rubiano A M, Shin S D., and others. 2018. “Strengthening Health Systems to Provide Emergency Care.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212058]
  39. Salti N, Brouwer E. D, Verguet S. 2016. “The Health, Financial, and Distributional Consequences of Increases in the Tobacco Excise Tax among Smokers in Lebanon.” Social Science and Medicine 170 (December): 161–69. [PMC free article: PMC5115647] [PubMed: 27792922]
  40. Sanders G D, Neumann P J, Basu A, Brock D W., and others. 2016. “Recommendations for Conduct, Methodological Practices, and Reporting of Cost-Effectiveness Analyses: Second Panel on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine.” Journal of the American Medical Association 316 (10): 1093–103. [PubMed: 27623463]
  41. Schäferhoff M, Fewer S, Kraus J, Richter E, Summers L H., and others. 2015. “How Much Donor Financing for Health Is Channelled to Global Versus Country-Specific Aid Functions?” The Lancet 386 (10011): 2436–41. [PubMed: 26178405]
  42. Skolnik R. 2016. Global Health 101 (third edition). Burlington, MA: Jones & Bartlett Learning.
  43. Smith P C. 2013. “Incorporating Financial Protection into Decision Rules for Publicly Financed Healthcare Treatments.” Health Economics 22 (2): 180–93. [PubMed: 22241688]
  44. Stenberg K, Hanssen O, Tan-Torres T, Edejer M, Bertram T., and others. 2017. “Financing Transformative Health Systems Towards Achievement of the Health Sustainable Development Goals: A Model for Projected Resource Needs in 67 Low-Income and Middle-Income Countries.” The Lancet Global Health. doi:http://dx​.doi.org/10​.1016/S2214-109X(17)30263-2. [PMC free article: PMC5554796] [PubMed: 28728918]
  45. Stigliz J, Sen A, Fitoussi J P. 2010. Mis-Measuring Our Lives: Why GDP Doesn’t Add Up. New York and London: The New Press.
  46. Trimble E L, Rajaraman P, Chao A, Gross T., and others. 2015. “Need for National Commitments to Cancer Research to Guide Public Health Investment and Practice.” In Disease Control Priorities (third edition): Volume 9, Cancer, edited by Gelband H, Jha P, Sankaranarayanan R, Horton S, editors. . Washington, D.C.: World Bank. [PubMed: 26913337]
  47. UN (United Nations). 2017. World Population Prospects: The 2017 Revision. New York: Population Division, United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs.
  48. Verguet S, Gauvreau C L, Mishra S, MacLennan M., and others. 2015. “The Consequences of Tobacco Tax on Household Health and Finances in Rich and Poor Smokers in China: An Extended Cost-Effectiveness Analysis.” The Lancet Global Health 3 (4): e206–e216. [PubMed: 25772692]
  49. Verguet S, Jamison D T. 2018. “Health Policy Analysis: Applications of Extended Cost-Effectiveness Analysis Methodology in Disease Control Priorities: (third edition).” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212165]
  50. Verguet S, Laxminarayan R, Jamison D T. 2015. “Universal Public Finance of Tuberculosis Treatment in India: An Extended Cost-Effectiveness Analysis.” Health Economics 24 (3): 318–32. [PubMed: 24497185]
  51. Watkins D A, Jamison D T, Mills A, Atun R, Danforth K., and others. 2018. “Universal Health Coverage and Essential Packages of Care.” In Disease Control Priorities (third edition): Volume 9, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank.
  52. Watkins D A, Norheim O F, Jha P, Jamison D T. 2017. “Mortality Impact of Acheiving Essential Universal Health Coverage in Low- and Lower Middle-Income Countries.” DCP3 Working Paper no. 21. World Bank, Washington, DC.
  53. Watkins D A, Nugent R A, Saxenian H, Yamey G., and others. 2018. “Intersectoral Policy Priorties for Health.” In Disease Control Priorities, Improving Health and Reducing Poverty, (third edition): Volume 9 edited by Jamison D T, Gelband H, Horton S, Jha P, Laxminarayan R, Mock C N, Nugent R, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank. [PubMed: 30212058]
  54. Watkins D A, Qi J, Horton S E, Brouwer E., and others. 2017. “Costs and Affordability of Essential Universal Health Coverage in Low- and Middle-Income Countries.” DCP3 Working Paper no. 20. World Bank, Washington, DC.
  55. Weatherall D, Greenwood B, Chee H L, Wasi P. 2006. “Science and Technology for Disease Control: Past, Present, and Future.” In Disease Control Priorities in Developing Countries, second edition, edited by Jamison D. T, Breman J G, Measham A R, Alleyne G, Claeson M, Evans D B, Jha P, Mills A, Musgrove P, editors. . Washington, DC: World Bank and Oxford University Press. [PubMed: 21250320]
  56. WHO (World Health Organization). 2010. The World Health Report 2010: Health Systems Financing: The Path to Universal Coverage. Geneva: WHO.
  57. Wilkinson T, Sculpher M J, Claxton K, Revill P., and others. 2016. “The International Decision Support Initiative Reference Case for Economic Evaluation: An Aid to Thought.” Value Health 19 (8): 921–28. [PubMed: 27987641]
  58. World Bank. 1993. World Development Report 1993: Investing in Health. New York: Oxford University Press. https:​//openknowledge​.worldbank.org/handle/10986/5976.
  59. Youngkong S. 2012. “Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis for Including Health Interventions in the Universal Health Coverage Benefit Package in Thailand.” PhD dissertation, Radboud University, Nijmegen, the Netherlands. [PubMed: 22999148]
© 2018 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank.

This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 IGO license (CC BY 3.0 IGO) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions:

Attribution—Please cite the work as follows: Patel, V., D. Chisholm., T. Dua, R. Laxminarayan, and M. E. Medina-Mora, editors. 2015. Mental, Neurological, and Substance Use Disorders. Disease Control Priorities, third edition, volume 4. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0426-7. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0 IGO

Translations—If you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation.

Third-party content—The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content contained within the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of any third-party-owned individual component or part contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of those third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you. If you wish to re-use a component of the work, it is your responsibility to determine whether permission is needed for that re-use and to obtain permission from the copyright owner. Examples of components can include, but are not limited to, tables, figures, or images.

All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Publishing and Knowledge Division, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: gro.knabdlrow@sthgirbup.

Bookshelf ID: NBK525278PMID: 30212150DOI: 10.1596/978-1-4648-0527-1_ch1

Views

  • PubReader
  • Print View
  • Cite this Page
  • PDF version of this title (7.6M)

Related information

  • PMC
    PubMed Central citations
  • PubMed
    Links to PubMed

Similar articles in PubMed

  • Review Economic Burden of Chronic Ill Health and Injuries for Households in Low- and Middle-Income Countries.[Disease Control Priorities: Im...]
    Review Economic Burden of Chronic Ill Health and Injuries for Households in Low- and Middle-Income Countries.
    Essue BM, Laba M., Knaul F, Chu A, Minh HV, Nguyen TKP, Jan S. Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty. 2017 Nov 27
  • Review Tuberculosis.[Major Infectious Diseases. 2017]
    Review Tuberculosis.
    Bloom BR, Atun R, Cohen T, Dye C, Fraser H, Gomez GB, Knight G, Murray M, Nardell E, Rubin E, et al. Major Infectious Diseases. 2017 Nov 3
  • Review Universal Health Coverage and Essential Packages of Care.[Disease Control Priorities: Im...]
    Review Universal Health Coverage and Essential Packages of Care.
    Watkins DA, Jamison DT, Mills T., Atun T., Danforth K, Glassman A, Horton S, Jha P, Kruk ME, Norheim OF, et al. Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty. 2017 Nov 27
  • Review Intersectoral Policy Priorities for Health.[Disease Control Priorities: Im...]
    Review Intersectoral Policy Priorities for Health.
    Watkins DA, Nugent R, Saxenian H, yamey G, Danforth K, González-Pier E, Mock CN, Jha P, Alwan A, Jamison DT. Disease Control Priorities: Improving Health and Reducing Poverty. 2017 Nov 27
  • Review Summary.[Cancer: Disease Control Priori...]
    Review Summary.
    Gelband H, Jha P, Sankaranarayanan R, Gauvreau CL, Horton S. Cancer: Disease Control Priorities, Third Edition (Volume 3). 2015 Nov 1
See reviews...See all...

Recent Activity

Your browsing activity is empty.

Activity recording is turned off.

Turn recording back on

See more...