NCBI Bookshelf. A service of the National Library of Medicine, National Institutes of Health.
Breman JG, Alilio MS, Mills A, editors. The Intolerable Burden of Malaria II: What's New, What's Needed: Supplement to Volume 71(2) of the American Journal of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene. Northbrook (IL): American Society of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene; 2004 Aug.
The Intolerable Burden of Malaria II: What's New, What's Needed: Supplement to Volume 71(2) of the American Journal of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene.
Show detailsArtemisinin-based combination therapies (ACTs) are generally regarded as vital in addressing the growing problem posed by the development of antimalarial resistance across sub-Saharan Africa. However, the costs of the new ACTs are likely to be significantly higher than current therapies. Therefore, it is important to examine formally the cost-effectiveness of the more effective yet more expensive ACTs before advocating a switch in policy. Importantly, any such economic evaluation must consider the temporal dynamics of drug resistance, and not just focus on the static question of whether switching today would be cost-effective at current levels of resistance, particularly since the development of new antimalarials in the future is so uncertain. However, predicting the future changes in drug resistance is a major difficulty in accurately quantifying the relative costs and health outcomes associated with different drug therapies over time. Here, we use a simple decision tree model to estimate the incremental cost-effectiveness of using ACTs, compared with persisting with current therapies, over 5-, 10-, and 15-year periods. We describe the dynamics of drug resistance using a general logistic growth function, in which the starting frequency of resistance and maximum growth may be altered. However, rather than make assumptions about the absolute rate at which resistance to ACTs will progress, we allow the ratio of the growth rate of resistance to ACTs relative to that of current therapies to vary. Defining the growth rate of ACT resistance in this manner allows us to calculate the threshold ratio at which ACTs would no longer appear cost-effective, for any starting conditions of resistance to current therapies and ACTs, and over any time period. The influence of uncertainty in other decision tree parameters on the threshold ratio values is also quantified, using Monte Carlo simulation techniques. This analysis shows that ACTs are more than 95% likely to be cost-effective under most conditions, other than very low levels of initial resistance to sulfadoxine/pyrimethamine and a five-year time frame. These predictions are conservative in that 95% certainty is a stringent decision rule favoring the rejection of new policies. The importance of other variables not included in the analysis for the robustness of the findings are discussed (e.g., consideration of the entire population at risk for malaria, the affordability of ACTs in specific settings, and the growth of resistance modeled according to population genetic parameters).
Introduction
In sub-Saharan Africa, the growth of resistance to the widely used and affordable antimalarial drugs such as chloroquine and sulfadoxine-pyrimethamine (SP) is recognized as a growing problem.1, 2 Artemisinin-based combination therapies (ACTs) are generally regarded as a vital component in addressing the crisis,3 with a range of ACTs shown to be highly effective in treating malaria in areas with high levels of first-line drug resistance.4 Moreover, theoretical arguments suggest that the use of antimalarial therapies in combination with artemisinin-derivatives will slow the rate at which resistance emerges.5, 6
However, the costs of the new ACTs are likely to be an order of magnitude more expensive than current therapies.7, 8 Therefore, it is important to examine formally the cost-effectiveness of the potentially more effective yet more expensive ACTs before advocating a switch in policy. Importantly, any such cost-effectiveness analysis must consider the temporal dynamics of drug resistance and not just focus on the static question of whether switching today would be cost-effective at current levels of resistance; as drug resistance emerges and spreads, the cost-effectiveness ratio changes depending on what time frame of analysis is chosen.9 These temporal considerations are particularly important in the case of ACTs, since the potential consequences are grave of having widespread resistance to artemisinin and its derivatives at some point in the future, without any alternative therapies.
However, predicting the future trajectory of drug resistance is extremely difficult, particularly for ACTs, which have yet to be widely used as first-line therapy in sub-Saharan Africa. As a result, basic knowledge about drug usage patterns, and the time to emergence and the rate of spread of resistance, are not yet available. In the absence of such basic parameters, we propose a theoretical approach to help understand the threshold conditions under which the introduction of ACTs is likely to be cost-effective relative to the strategy of retaining a monotherapy as first-line treatment. The analysis uses a simple decision tree framework that allows the disease burden and costs associated with a first-line antimalarial treatment to be estimated, while explicitly taking into account the growth of resistance to treatments through time. The threshold conditions under which ACTs are cost-effective relative to retaining a monotherapy are described as a function of two main variables: 1) the growth rate of resistance of the ACT therapy relative to the monotherapy, and 2) the starting level of resistance of the monotherapy. While the model is generic, in that it can be used to examine a range of alternative first-line scenarios, we restrict our detailed analysis to comparing the cost-effectiveness of artemisinin-based combination drugs relative to a baseline scenario of retaining SP over a set period of time. The importance of the results and the usefulness of the novel quantitative approach are discussed.
Methods
A simple decision tree, based on a previous model used to evaluate the optimal time to switch first line antimalarial therapies,9 was developed to quantify the cost-effectiveness of using an ACT rather than an existing therapy over a fixed number of years, N. The decision tree, shown in Figure 1, follows the possible outcome of a patient presenting with malaria and receiving first-line treatment. In the first instance, the patient may be either cured or experience treatment failure. Cure was defined as adequate clinical response following criteria of the World Health Organization.10 The average health consequences (expressed as disability adjusted life years [DALYs]) and costs (US$ 2002) per patient associated with a given first-line drug regimen, may then be calculated by following the decision tree paths to the end points as shown in Figure 1 and Table 1. The decision is considered from a provider’s perspective, and is restricted to those true malaria cases presenting at formal outpatient facilities, with the out-patient population weighted by the proportions <5 years old and ≥5 years old ( Table 1).11
Treatment failure
The probability of treatment failure, F, (P25 and P26 in Figure 1 and Table 1) with a given first line drug, i, at time t was defined as being dependent on three main inputs: first, the proportion of malaria parasites, R, resistant to drug i at time t; second, the probability, m, that a patient complies at the recommended dose with drug therapy i; and third, the probability, p, that therapy i is effective despite the patient failing to comply fully with the treatment regimen.
We assumed that any patient infected with resistant parasites experiences treatment failure, regardless of whether they fully comply with the treatment regimen. As such, there are only two possible ways in which treatment with drug i at time t may be successful. First, the patient is not infected with resistant parasites and fully complies with the treatment regimen; the probability of this occurring is (1 – R i,t ) m i . Alternatively, the patient may be infected with susceptible parasites but, despite not complying with the treatment regimen, is still cured; the probability of this occurring is (1 – R i,t )(1 – m i ) p i . The overall probability of treatment success is the sum of these two probabilities, while treatment failure is simply one minus treatment success. Thus
defines treatment failure, which simplifies to
The dynamic spread of drug resistance through time was modeled using a logistic growth function of the form
where R i ,0 is the level of drug resistance to treatment i at the start of the N-year time period; k i is the maximum possible level of drug resistance, which cannot exceed 1 (i.e., at k i = 1 the entire malarial parasite population would be resistant to drug i); and r i is the maximum growth rate of resistance against drug i, which occurs when R i ,0 approaches zero.
We assume m i and p i remain constant with time over the N- year period of evaluation, although in practice patient compliance is likely to be influenced by the effectiveness of the drug (and in turn, the rate of development of resistance will also be dependent on patient usage patterns). The dynamics of treatment failure, as described by equation 2, are driven by the growth of resistance given by equation 3. To illustrate this, Figure 2 shows the temporal changes in treatment failure for two alternative drug regimens used over a 10-year period as predicted by equations 2 and 3.
DALYs and costs
The decision tree allows the average costs, c, associated with first-line treatment failure, c i , F , and success, c i,S , to be calculated (Figure 1 and Table 1). Similarly, the average DALY burden associated with treatment failure, e i,F , and success, e i,S , may also be estimated. The total costs, C, over the full N-year period associated with using drug i as the first line treatment, were then calculated as
and the total DALY burden, E, incurred over the same period was estimated as
where δ is the annual discount rate. The incremental cost effectiveness ratio (ICER) of using an ACT relative to the existing drug, X, over the full N-year period was given as
The DALYs were calculated using standard methods,12 assuming age-specific life expectancies based on a United Nations west African life table with average life expectancy of 50 years at birth and a 3% discount rate. The costing methodology followed that described by Goodman and others,11, 13 and used the ingredients approach, with all prices converted to 2002 US dollars.
Drug regimen comparison and parameter values
The model was anchored to the real world by using the framework to compare the use of either SP or an ACT as a first-line therapy in a high transmission setting of a low-income, sub-Saharan African country (as defined by Goodman and others11). A baseline time period of N= 10 years (varied to a minimum of 5 years and maximum of 15 years) and a discount rate of 3% (varied to 0%) per year were chosen.
The maximum growth rate of SP resistance, r SP , was estimated from longitudinal drug resistance studies conducted in eastern and southern Africa.14 The maximum growth rate of ACT, r ACT , was defined relative to r SP , with the ratio r ACT /r SP varied from 0.05 upwards. The baseline starting condition for ACT resistance at t= 0 was set at 0.001 (i.e., one parasite per 1,000 would show resistance to the ACT), and was also varied to a maximum of 0.01 (i.e., one parasite per 100 showing resistance).
All input parameter values and their sources are shown in Table 1. Scarcity of data restricted parameter definitions to best estimates and likely ranges, represented by triangular distributions.9 However, to redistribute probability density to its most likely form, standard distributions were fitted to the triangles by minimizing the square of the distance between the two distributions. Standard beta distributions, bounded by 0 and 1, were appropriate for parameters representing probabilities. Lognormal distributions, bounded by 0 with a positive skew, were appropriate for parameters representing costs, since there is a marginal likelihood that variable costs may be disproportionately high. Point estimates were used for parameters for which uncertainty was not reported or unknown, such as disability weights, or parameters that were known with absolute certainty.
A continuous, linear cost function with zero fixed costs was assumed. Consequently, a child’s dose, assumed to be 50% of an adult dose, cost 50% of the adult dose. The range for the cost of ACT was made from estimates for artesunate/SP (low estimate), Co-Artem®(Novartis International AG, Basel, Switzerland) artemether-lumefantrine (best estimate), and artesunate/mefloquine (high estimate).
The model does not take into account policy change costs. In practice, a range of costs, such as improved diagnostics and regulatory measures, may accompany a change in treatment regimes (e.g., to a more advanced drug such as ACT). The magnitude of these costs is currently unknown.
Monte Carlo simulation and threshold estimation
For combinations of SP starting resistance and values of r ACT /r SP , the model was iterated 3,000 times. At each iteration, input parameter values were chosen at random from the probability distributions defined in Table 1, and the ICER of using an ACT relative to SP over the N-year time period calculated according to equation 6. The calculated ICER was compared with a cut-off value of $150/DALY averted, a rough economic evaluation criterion by which a health intervention in a developing country may be judged to be “attractive”.15 For any starting condition of SP resistance, the threshold value of the ratio r ACT /r SP at which 95% of the model iterations were cost-effective at the $150/DALY level was then recorded. A cost-effectiveness probability surface was drawn to show the threshold conditions under which the use of the ACT over the N-year period would be considered cost-effective with 95% certainty at the $150/DALY level.
Standard acceptability curves were constructed to represent uncertainty around the $150/DALY averted decision rule, and to make cost-effectiveness results comparable to opportunity costs represented by other medical interventions. To make this analysis possible, we chose scenarios with starting levels of resistance to SP at 10%, 30%, and 50%, and with resistance growing at an equal trajectory for both drugs (r ACT /r SP = 1). To quantify the levels of cost-effectiveness given in these figures, and to allow for considerations of affordability, per-person incremental costs, incremental DALYs averted, and cost-effectiveness ratios were recorded.
The model iterations were conducted in Microsoft (Redmond, WA) Excel® using the @Risk add-in tool (Palisade Corporation, Newfield, NY).
Results
The model results are shown in Figure 3. For the baseline scenario with a 10-year period of comparison, 3% annual discount rate, and starting ACT resistance frequency of 0.001, the threshold values of the ratio r ACT /r SP vary from approximately 1.5 (at a 10% starting level of SP resistance) to 5 (at a 60% starting level of SP resistance) i.e., resistance to ACT would have to grow 1.5 times faster than resistance to SP monotherapy for acts to be the preferred policy option. Above 60% resistance to SP, ACTs are predicted to be cost-effective at all considered values of r ACT /r SP .
The effects of varying the time frame to 5 and 15 years are clearly evident. Under the five-year scenario, the slope of the threshold condition is much steeper, and importantly, below an SP resistance starting condition of approximately 20%, the ICER 95% confidence intervals lie above the $150/DALY criterion. However, between 20% and 40%, the ACT option is robustly cost-effective, with the threshold values for r ACT /r SP lying between 3 and 5. Above 40%, ACTs are predicted to be cost-effective for all considered values of r ACT /r SP . In contrast, under the 15-year scenario, the slope of the threshold condition is shallower, with less certainty that the ACT option will be cost-effective at high levels of r ACT /r SP .
Figure 4 shows the impact of increasing the starting condition of ACT drug resistance by an order of magnitude from 0.001 to 0.01. For all times frames, the critical threshold value of the r ACT /r SP ratio was significantly lower when using the higher starting frequency of ACT resistance. The effects of varying the discount rate to zero were negligible and the results did not noticeably differ from those shown in Figures 3 and 4.
The impact of variations in the $150/DALY averted decision rule used to determine cost-effectiveness is shown in Figure 5. As starting levels of resistance to SP increase, cost-effectiveness becomes more robust to changes in the decision rule over a five-year time horizon. The decision rule has no impact on cost-effectiveness after 10 years or 15 years.
Tables 2 and 3 show the means of incremental per-person costs incurred, incremental DALYs averted, and ICER for each starting condition for SP-resistance and an r ACT /r SP ratio equal to 1. As R SP,0 (i.e., the starting level of resistance to SP at time t = 0) increases, incremental costs decrease, incremental DALYs increase, and ACTs become more cost-effective.
Discussion
Given the dynamic nature of drug resistance, with the effects of drug policies implemented today affecting the levels of drug resistance in the future, quantitative models are required to predict the likely effects6, 16, 17 and cost-effectiveness,9, 18, 19 of alternative policies aimed at ameliorating the disease burden associated with drug resistance. The analytical framework described here provides a succinct means of examining the complex and uncertain issues associated with comparing the cost-effectiveness of alternative antimalarial drug therapies. Importantly, rather than making absolute predictions of the rate at which ACT drug resistance will develop, an as yet unknown quantity, we allow the ratio of the growth rate of resistance to ACTs relative to that of current therapies to vary across a range of fixed values. Defining the growth rate of ACT resistance in this manner allows us to calculate the threshold ratio at which ACTs would no longer appear cost-effective, for any starting conditions of resistance to current therapies and ACTs, and over any time period. Also, the influences of uncertainty in other decision tree parameters on the threshold conditions are quantified using Monte Carlo simulation techniques.
The results of the simulations highlight the importance of the time frame of economic evaluation when evaluating dynamic systems.9 Taking a relatively short-term perspective (five years) shows a threshold of SP resistance below which it is not cost-effective to switch to an ACT, using the 95% decision rule. No such lower SP resistance threshold is seen with the longer 10-year and 15-year time frames. Across much of eastern and southern Africa, the level of SP drug resistance is already approximately 30% or more.14 At such levels of SP resistance, the model is consistent in its predictions, regardless of the time frame, or the assumption of initial ACT resistance levels, and the growth rate of resistance of the ACT would have to be significantly greater than that observed with SP for the ACT not to remain cost effective. Moreover, as is intuitively predictable, the higher the level of SP resistance, the more rapidly ACT drug resistance would have to spread for it not to be a cost-effective replacement strategy. At high initial levels of SP resistance, the decision to switch to ACTs is nearly certain, resistance to ACTs would have to grow extremely rapidly for them not to be cost-effective.
It should also be noted that the predicted thresholds are conservative for two reasons. First, the chosen comparator, SP, has a higher estimated compliance (since it is taken as a single dose), and thus a lower expected failure rate for a given level of resistance, relative to other existing therapies such as amodiaquine and chloroquine. Second, the threshold condition under which the ACT strategy fails to be cost-effective was based on a stringent 95% decision rule. It has been argued that a 50% threshold should be adopted as a basis for determining cost-effectiveness.20 Adoption of a lower certainty criterion would raise the level of the threshold boundary across all time frames (i.e., expand the cost-effective area of the economic evaluation planes shown in Figure 3). Nevertheless the 95% cut-off is useful since decision makers tend to be risk adverse in sanctioning policy changes,9 and given the financial implications of advocating a significantly more expensive drug, the greater the certainty of cost-effectiveness the more helpful is the analysis in informing policy decisions.
To interpret the results from this model, consideration must be made of the unregulated prescription of combination therapy drugs. If one or both of the component drugs is made available individually through the private or informal sectors, resistance to the combination therapy is likely to develop more rapidly. A similar argument may be made for drugs that act through similar mechanisms, such as artesunate and artemether, in which resistance to one drug will have negative effects on the efficacy of the other. However, the availability of drugs through the private sector will impact on the growth of resistance of all alternative first-line therapies, ACTs as well as currently used therapies such as SP. Therefore, private sector availability may be neutral in its impact on the relative growth of ACT and SP resistance. However, even if private sector availability impacts differentially more on the growth rate of resistance to ACT, it seems unlikely that the impact could be so great as to alter the decision for a policy switch under the majority of the settings represented by the parameter space in Figures 3 and 4.
The structure of the model is flexible in that it can be adapted to examine a range of alternative first-line treatments, and, through varying the input parameters, to analyze specific epidemiologic and economic scenarios. The framework may also be used to quantify the influence of key variables on the location of the threshold conditions. Three key variables that should be further examined as more empirical data become available are 1) the expected cost of the ACT, including not only drug price but other costs associated with its implementation, 2) the level of compliance to the ACTs, and 3) the initial level of drug resistance, as shown by the difference in threshold conditions in Figure 3(initial ACT resistance set at 1 in 1,000) and Figure 4(initial ACT resistance set at 1 in 100).
While the model performs well in avoiding the problem associated with a lack of basic knowledge on the key parameter of ACT growth of resistance, it has several limitations that may influence the predicted outcomes. First, the framework is based on a previous model that focused only on the population seeking care through formal inpatient/outpatient facilities. It does not consider the whole population at risk of malaria, nor accommodate the range of patient-seeking behaviors in, for example, the private sector. Second, although a logistic function is used to capture the temporal dynamics of resistance, there is no link between the growth rate of resistance and those factors dictating the evolution of resistance, such as drug pressure, compliance to drug regimens, drug decay rates, and parasite recombination rates. Also, the links between levels of treatment failure, patient compliance, and overall patterns of drug usage are also dynamic, which is not captured. Third, the effects of transmission intensity and other malaria interventions are not included; rather the model is restricted to the presentation of true malaria-positive individuals and does not accommodate changes in underlying rates of malaria in different sections of the population. Fourth, cost-effectiveness is only one criterion on which policy decisions are based. Importantly, cost-effectiveness estimates are not informative for issues of affordability. Since the exclusive use of a cost-effectiveness threshold theoretically can lead to a prescription for unlimited expansion of the health service, it will be necessary to account for affordability in further work.
While all four shortfalls of the approach should be addressed by future research, ideally through theoretical developments guided by empirically measured parameters, the model presented here provides a structured means of robustly quantifying the likely range of conditions under which switching from SP to an ACT is likely to be cost-effective. Crucially, given current limited production of ACTs, a considerable amount of forward planning and logistical support must be in place to ensure that ACTs are widely available before advocating a switch in policy.
Acknowledgments
We thank Andrew Briggs for facilitating the collaboration between the Health Economics Research Centre (University of Oxford) and the London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine and for his input to the modeling.
References
- 1.
- Nosten F, van Vugt M, Price R, Luxemburger C, Thway KL, Brockman A, McGready R, ter Kuile F, Looareesuwan S, White NJ. Viewpoint: averting a malaria disaster. Lancet. 1999;353:1965–1967. [PubMed: 11071185]
- 2.
- Bloland PB, Kazembe PN, Oloo AJ, Himonga B, Barat LM, Ruebush TK. Chloroquine in Africa: critical assessment and recommendations for monitoring and evaluating chloroquine therapy efficacy in sub-Saharan Africa. Trop Med Int Health. 1998;3:543–552. [PubMed: 9705188]
- 3.
- Bloland PB, Ettling M, Meek S. Combination therapy for African malaria: hype or hope? Bull World Health Organ. 2000;78:1378–1388. [PMC free article: PMC2560651] [PubMed: 11196485]
- 4.
- McIntosh HM, Olliaro P, 2002. Artemisinin derivatives for treating uncomplicated malaria. Cochrane Database Systematic Review. [PMC free article: PMC6532741] [PubMed: 10796519]
- 5.
- White NJ. Delaying antimalarial drug resistance with combination chemotherapy. Parassitologia. 1999;41:301–308. [PubMed: 10697872]
- 6.
- Hastings IM, Watkins WM, White NJ. The evolution of drug-resistant malaria: the role of drug elimination half-life. Philos Trans R Soc Lond B Biol Sci. 2002;357:505–519. [PMC free article: PMC1692966] [PubMed: 12028788]
- 7.
- Kindermans JM, Pécoul B, Perez-Casas C, Den Boer M, Berman D, Cox I, 2002. Changing National Malaria Treatment Protocols in Africa: What Is the Cost and Who Will Pay? Médicins sans Frontières Campaign for Access to Essential Medicines. Background Paper for the Roll Back Malaria Partnership Meeting on Improving Access to Antimalarial Treatment. Geneva: World Health Organization. September 30 to October 2.
- 8.
- Bloland PB, 2001. Drug Resistance in Malaria. Geneva: World Health Organization.
- 9.
- Goodman CA, Coleman PG, Mills A. Changing the first line drug for malaria treatment - cost-effectiveness with highly uncertain inter-temporal trade-offs. Health Econ. 2001;10:731–749. [PubMed: 11747054]
- 10.
- WHO/CTD, 1996. Assessment of Therapeutic Efficacy of Antimalarial Drugs for Uncomplicated Falciparum Malaria with Intense Transmission. Geneva: World Health Organization. WHO/MAL/96.1077.
- 11.
- Goodman CA, Coleman PG, Mills A. Cost-effectiveness of malaria control in sub-Saharan Africa. Lancet. 1999;354:378–385. [PubMed: 10437867]
- 12.
- Murray CJL, Lopez AD, 1996. The Global Burden of Disease: A Comprehensive Assessment of Mortality and Disability from Diseases, Injuries, and Risk Factors in 1990 and Projected to 2020. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
- 13.
- Goodman CA, Coleman PG, Mills A, 2000. Economic Analysis of Malaria Control in Sub-Saharan Africa. Geneva: World Health Organization. Global Forum for Health Research.
- 14.
- Roper C, Pearce R, Bredenkamp B, Gumede J, Drakeley C, Mosha F, Chandramohan D, Sharp B. Antifolate anti-malarial resistance in southeast Africa: a population-based analysis. Lancet. 2003;361:1174–1181. [PubMed: 12686039]
- 15.
- WHO, 1996. Investing in Health Research and Development: Report of the Ad Hoc Committee in Health Research Relating to Future Intervention Options. Geneva: World Health Organization. TDR/Gen/96.1.
- 16.
- Curtis CF, Otoo LN. A simple model of the build-up of resistance to mixtures of anti-malarial drugs. Trans R Soc Trop Med Hyg. 1986;80:889–892. [PubMed: 3603638]
- 17.
- Hastings IM, D’Alessandro U. Modelling a predictable disaster: the rise and spread of drug-resistant malaria. Parasitol Today. 2000;16:340–347. [PubMed: 10900482]
- 18.
- Phillips M, Phillips-Howard PA. Economic implications of resistance to antimalarial drugs. Pharmacoeconomics. 1996;10:225–238. [PubMed: 10163571]
- 19.
- Sudre P, Breman JG, McFarland D, Koplan JP. Treatment of chloroquine-resistant malaria in African children: a cost-effectiveness analysis. Int J Epidemiol. 1992;21:146–154. [PubMed: 1544746]
- 20.
- Claxton K. The irrelevance of inference: a decision-making approach to the stochastic evaluation of health care technologies. J Health Econ. 1999;18:341–364. [PubMed: 10537899]
- 21.
- Kindermans JM, 2002. ACTs: Availability and Prices. Geneva: World Health Organization. Presentation at Roll Back Malaria Partners Meeting, October 1.
Footnotes
Received August 21, 2003. Accepted for publication December 8, 2003.
Financial support: This study was supported by the Institute of Medicine and the World Health Organization.
Authors’ addresses: Paul G. Coleman, Disease Control and Vector Biology Unit, Department of Infectious and Tropical Diseases, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, Keppel Street, London WC1E 7HT, United Kingdom, Telephone: 44-207-927-2333, Fax: 44-207-580-9075. E-mail: Paul.Coleman@lshtm.ac.uk. Chantal Morel, Catherine Goodman, and Anne J. Mills, Health Economics and Financing Program, Department of Public Health and Policy, Health Policy Unit, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine, Keppel Street, London WC1E 7HT, United Kingdom, E-mails: Chantal.Morel@lshtm.ac.uk, Catherine.Goodman@lshtm.ac.uk, and Anne.Mills@lshtm.ac.uk. Samuel Shillcutt, Health Economics Research Centre, University of Oxford, Old Road, Headington, Oxford OX3 7LF, United Kingdom and Department of Economics, School of Social Sciences, City University, Northampton Square, London EC1V 0HB, United Kingdom, E-mail: Samuel.Shillcutt@public-health.oxford.ac.uk.
- A Threshold Analysis of the Cost-Effectiveness of Artemisinin-based Combination ...A Threshold Analysis of the Cost-Effectiveness of Artemisinin-based Combination Therapies in Sub-Saharan Africa - The Intolerable Burden of Malaria II: What's New, What's Needed
Your browsing activity is empty.
Activity recording is turned off.
See more...