NCBI Bookshelf. A service of the National Library of Medicine, National Institutes of Health.
Institute of Medicine (US); Gray BH, editor. The New Health Care for Profit: Doctors and Hospitals in a Competitive Environment. Washington (DC): National Academies Press (US); 1983.
The New Health Care for Profit: Doctors and Hospitals in a Competitive Environment.
Show detailsStephen M. Shortell
People in the future will need to learn organization the way their forefathers learned farming.
— Peter Drucker
Medical decision making is an organizational process. Even at the level of individual clinical judgment, a myriad of prior "organizational" decisions have been made that affect what appears to be an autonomous clinical judgment made by a trained professional. For example, a surgeon's choice of a given technique for a particular operation has been conditioned by prior decisions, such as the number and types of operating rooms available, types of equipment purchased, the quality and mix of surgical assistants and nursing staff, and the organization of the operating room schedule itself. The surgeon's decision may also be influenced by prior decisions made by the hospital's quality assurance committee. In brief, "micro" decisions involving individual clinical judgment and "macro" decisions involving larger organization-wide resource allocation and policy issues are highly interrelated. The nature of physician involvement in hospital decision making must be understood within this context.
There are five major themes to this paper. The first is that the major hospital decision makers—trustees; administrators; voluntary staff physicians; hospital-compensated physicians; and, increasingly, nurses—will view the decision-making process primarily as a function of their actual degree of involvement in the organization, the degree of involvement that they feel they should have, and the nature of the issue at stake. Physicians and nurses typically will be most concerned about decisions affecting patient care—the ultimate goal. Administrators and trustees, although also concerned about patient care, will focus most of their energies on resource acquisition and management issues—the instrumental goals for facilitating cost-effective patient care.
The second theme of this paper is that the distinction between "clinical" and "administrative" decision making is becoming blurred. New technology, regulation, and competitive forces are giving rise to a number of decisions in which no single professional group has controlling interest and participation by all groups is required.
The third theme is that physician involvement in hospital decision making is affected by whether the hospital is voluntary or investor-owned, a freestanding hospital or a member of a multi-unit system.* For example, a hospital that becomes part of an investor-owned chain may find its physicians more actively involved in hospital governing board activities than previously.
The fourth theme is that decision making may be moving away from the "dual authority" model of split administrative and clinical decisions to a more "shared authority" model based on increasing collaboration between administrators and physicians. This is partly because of the blurring of decisions noted above but is also due to a number of other factors that will be discussed.
The fifth theme is organized around some evidence that suggests that greater physician involvement in hospital-wide decision making is associated with lower costs and higher-quality care. In this context the relationship between cost containment and quality of care also is examined.
Where relevant, these themes are specifically considered for their implications regarding for-profit ownership of hospitals. This is particularly true in regard to the types of decisions faced, dual authority and shared authority decision-making models, and specific forms of physician involvement in decision making. At the same time it is important to recognize that the differences in economic orientation between for-profit and nonprofit hospitals may be narrowing, with some interesting implications for hospital behavior.
For brevity's sake, this paper will not describe the historical evolution of physician involvement in hospital decision making. The main concern here is with current developments and implications for the immediate future. The paper will not serve as an exhaustive review of the literature. Rather, it will highlight some of the more significant studies and major findings.
This paper is divided into five major sections. First, the major kinds of decisions made by hospitals are described. Second, those individuals primarily involved in hospital decisions are noted, and two models of decision making are examined. Third, the nature of the involvement is highlighted. Fourth, evidence bearing on the relationship between physician/hospital decision making and the cost and quality of care is summarized. Finally, a number of future issues influencing physician/hospital decision making are discussed.
A Typology of Hospital Decision Making
A simple typology of decision making is shown in Table 1, which suggests that decision-making strategies used by hospitals depend on (1) the degree of agreement or certainty among the key parties as to their preferences for specific outcomes and (2) the degree of confidence or certainty in the cause-effect relationships involved—i.e., whether the decision will actually produce the desired results. For example, in the first cell where all parties agree on preferences about outcomes and the certainty of cause-effect relationships is relatively straightforward, decisions can be made on a fairly routine "computational" basis. Decisions involving the amount of standard supplies to keep in inventory in the hospital's central supply department serves as an example of a computational decision strategy. For the most part, physicians do not get involved in such decisions, which are primarily made by hospital support department heads and increasingly are being computerized or otherwise automated.
The second cell involves situations in which there is certainty about cause-effect relationships but in which the parties involved disagree about desired outcomes. These decisions are labeled ''compromise'' decisions. For example, a hospital may be faced with the decision of whether to purchase a CT scanner or expand the laboratory department's capabilities. In either case the cause-effect relationships are known (the decision will most likely result in improved patient care), but the parties disagree as to the areas of hospital operation (radiology or lab) in which they wish to see the improvement. It is important to note that general economic forces, external regulation, and competitive pressures are increasing the number of compromise decisions that hospitals must make. These are situations where the efficacies of decisions are known but where there are insufficient funds to implement all of them. Compromise decisions are a major area of physician involvement in hospital decision making, as each specialty group strives to maintain or expand its scope of responsibility. Thus, for the most part, physicians become involved in these decisions in order to protect their interests.
The third cell involves situations in which preferences about outcomes are known and agreed upon but where there is uncertainty about the cause-effect relationships. These situations constitute "judgmental" decisions. For example, the decision to improve a hospital's financial position may be agreed upon by all parties, but uncertainty may exist about the best strategy or combination of strategies to accomplish this. Physicians are becoming increasingly involved in judgmental decisions but for a different reason than their involvement in compromise decisions. In compromise decisions they become involved primarily to protect their interests, but in judgmental decisions they become involved because their expertise as physicians is needed. For example, many administrators have relied heavily on physician advice in justifying major capital purchases or expansion projects to health systems agencies.
The fourth cell describes situations in which uncertainty exists about both preferences for outcomes and cause-effect relationships. These decisions are labeled "inspirational." For example, a rural hospital with low occupancy may be pondering whether to develop an ambulatory care program or affiliate with an urban medical center. In terms of cause and effect it is not clear that either option will increase admissions. Furthermore, with either option the parties involved may disagree about likely outcomes. To reduce the uncertainty surrounding such decisions, hospitals are increasingly adopting methods of formal environmental assessment and long-run strategic planning.
Their purpose is to transfer these decisions from the inspirational category to the judgmental or compromise categories. In this process medical opinion is becoming increasingly important, resulting in further physician involvement in hospital decision making.
Because new technology, regulation, and competition have given rise to a great number of compromise, judgmental, and inspirational decisions, physicians and administrators have found themselves more dependent on each other, and the distinction between clinical and administrative decision making is blurring. Three prototypical decision examples help illustrate the point.
The first example has to do with whether a hospital should expand its ambulatory care activities, perhaps by developing a satellite clinic or a health promotion program or by sponsoring a group practice. Although a number of marketing, planning, and related administrative considerations are involved in such a decision, clinical issues are intertwined throughout. These include issues of what kinds of patients will be treated, triage, specialty mix of the physicians involved, determination of clinical privileges, and the type of referral relationships to be established. A hospital's decision to expand its ambulatory care activities can often be controversial and divisive because it may directly threaten existing staff who are trying to maintain or expand their practices. Thus, the administrative and clinical considerations involved take on added importance.
The second example is represented by the question of whether to pay hospital-based specialists, such as pathologists and radiologists, a percentage of the gross revenues generated or a percentage of the net revenues generated. From an administrative and cost containment perspective, payment based on the percentage of gross revenue offers no incentive for efficiency, but payment based on the percentage of net revenue creates an incentive to contain expenses. However, economic and administrative considerations also must take into account some underlying clinical issues. These include the effect of the compensation method on the general quality of the staff in the laboratory and radiology departments, on the institution's ability to keep up with technological advances and to offer new tests and services desired by medical staff members, and on the general maintenance of the quality of care.
A third example is represented by the question of whether to change from team nursing, in which a group of nurses care for a group of patients, to primary care nursing, in which one nurse and often an assistant are assigned responsibility for managing a patient's care throughout the patient's stay. A variety of administrative and clinical issues are raised by such a decision. They include cost considerations, likely impact on turnover, absenteeism, job satisfaction, ability to recruit nurses, relationship with other departments, continuity of care, and quality of care. These issues are interrelated and difficult to separate, even though each group will approach the question from its particular area of concern—nurses from the perspective of job satisfaction and quality of patient care, physicians from their perspective of quality of care and how the change will affect nurse/physician relationships, and administrators from the perspective of costs and adequacy of staffing in addition to concerns about quality of care.
Other examples could be used to illustrate the blurring of administrative and clinical decision making. Some additional examples are provided in Table 2, categorized according to the computational, compromise, judgmental, and inspirational frameworks.
Although it provides some insight, the typology described above is oversimplified. At least two other sources of complexity appear to be important in understanding the nature of the hospital decision-making process. The first is the influence of differences in ownership of hospitals—particularly in regard to voluntary versus investor-owned hospitals and freestanding hospitals versus those belonging to multi-unit systems. The second is the distinction between those matters in which physician and hospital interests coincide and those in which they are more likely to be in conflict.
A basic distinction between investor-owned and voluntary hospitals is the former's need to make a return on stockholders' equity. This return might be viewed as the ultimate goal of the investor-owned hospital with the rendering of patient care serving as an instrumental goal or means of achieving the ultimate goal of return on equity. In contrast, for the voluntary hospital the ultimate goal is the delivery of patient care to the community and generating a surplus (or profit) serves as an instrumental goal or means by which this is achieved. In brief, the means-ends relationships become reversed.
It is important to note that for both investor-owned and voluntary hospitals financial viability and the delivery of cost-effective patient care are important, whether as instrumental or ultimate goals. Nevertheless, one might hypothesize that this difference will affect the decision-making process and the resulting choices of specific services offered by hospitals. The investor-owned hospital will presumably be particularly interested in adding services that will increase return on investment. From the overall portfolio or mix of services provided by a hospital, the requirement for profitability provides a constraint on expansionary impulses. Voluntary hospitals under traditional cost-based reimbursement have been able to develop a wide range of services to meet community needs or demands. In recent years, with the growth of regulation and competition, voluntary hospitals have also had to become more selective in adding new services and programs. Thus, a more fine-grained analysis of decision-making differences by investor-owned and voluntary hospitals is required. The decision framework presented in Table 1 provides a context for such analysis.
Specifically, investor-owned hospitals are likely to face somewhat more computational and judgmental decisions, while voluntary hospitals are likely to experience somewhat more compromise and inspirational decisions. As will be recalled, in computational and judgmental decisions preferences about outcomes are more certain. This is more likely to be true in investor-owned hospitals both because they are a part of systems typically characterized by the centralized influence of corporate offices and because of the more homogeneous group of defined constituents in terms of stockholders. In contrast, voluntary community hospitals have many different constituents to serve. They also tend to have high turnover in upper administrative ranks, and, therefore, many lack strong continuous managerial direction. In brief, there are likely to be more debates about the preferences for different kinds of outcomes in voluntary community hospitals than in investor-owned hospitals. As such, in voluntary hospitals the decision-making process may be somewhat more complex and indeterminate than in investor-owned hospitals.
In general, hospitals belonging to a multi-unit system seem likely to be more involved in computational and judgmental decisions than are freestanding individual hospitals. This is due in part to the influence of a corporate headquarters office with greater managerial staff expertise, which can reduce the uncertainty of cause-effect relationships surrounding given decisions. Also, the presence of an overall corporate mission and value system can help orient individual hospitals toward achievement of more common objectives, resulting in less disagreement regarding desired outcomes. In contrast, individual hospitals, often lacking such expertise and direction, may become involved in more compromise and inspirational decisions. These suggested differences, however, also depend on other factors, including the maturity of the multi-unit system and its emphasis on innovation. For example, a multi-unit system in the early years of existence may face a greater number of compromise decisions as it attempts to gain agreement among member hospitals regarding overall directions. Furthermore, a system at the cutting edge is experimenting with new programs, services, and organizational arrangements and may thus face a high number of inspirational decisions. Decision-making strategies will also be influenced by the degree of centralization that exists between the corporate headquarters office and individual member hospitals. The suggested differences by ownership and system status are summarized in Table 3.
Convergence versus Divergence of Interests
Determining where physician and hospital interests overlap and where they diverge is difficult because the relationship is subject to complex and rapidly changing forces. In general, hospital and physician interests coincide most often in areas involving expansion of hospital programs and services that are complementary rather than substitutable with physician services. Examples include increasing the number of beds; acquiring sophisticated technology, such as nuclear magnetic resonance scanners; and adding selected support services, such as occupational therapy, physical therapy, and social work, which are uneconomical for most physicians to incorporate into their private practices. Interests also coincide when physicians and hospitals can assist each other in responding to external regulation or changes in payment. A noteworthy example is the development of quality assurance committees in response to the establishment of Professional Standards Review Organizations (PSROs).
Conversely, hospital/physician interests diverge when physicians perceive the hospital to be in direct competition or when the hospital believes physicians are acting counter to the long-run objective of the hospital. Thus, as previously noted, hospitals' efforts to expand their ambulatory care activities may meet medical staff opposition because of fear of direct competition for patients and hospital beds. 2 Opposition may also be based on philosophical objections to the "corporate practice of medicine." Regulations or changes in payment also can create conflict rather than representing the "common enemy" against which hospitals and physicians can unite. For example, limiting hospital revenues by reimbursing on a case-mix basis may create conflict between a hospital's economic interests and the physicians' economic and professional interests.
It is important to note that there is frequently more disagreement among physicians than between physicians and hospitals. Physicians are not a unitary group and seldom act in concert on a given issue. Differences exist by specialty, years in practice, and geographical location, in addition to individual differences in personality and philosophy. For example, surgeons and other specialists are typically strong supporters of hospital ambulatory care programs because they usually benefit directly from increased referrals. Primary care physicians, in contrast, are likely to be the most vocal critics because of perceived competition. Even here, differences exist depending on the patients to be served. For example, if the primary purpose of an expanded ambulatory care program is to serve more Medicaid patients, private practice physicians may be supportive because of their desire to limit the number of Medicaid patients in their practice.
The diversity among physicians is important to recognize in considering decisions involving almost any new program, service, technology, or reorganization. In brief, each physician and specialty group will be concerned if the decision is likely to benefit other groups or interests more than their own. As Harris3 notes, in the extreme, this results in
... each clinical service of the medical staff ... striving to maintain and expand the magnitude of its own defensive position.... Each service gets its own intensive care unit. Each intensive care unit gets its own laboratory. The idea behind all of these arrangements is to insure the exclusive availability of a set of inputs to a small group of demanders. In that way no one is going to get bumped.
Although this often creates problems for hospital administrators and trustees, it also is to their advantage in that it facilitates "divide and conquer" strategies and affords administrators some flexibility in playing off the interests of one group of physicians against another. How these relationships are influenced by competition, regulation, and related factors is described in a subsequent section.
The Decision Makers
The most important point to understand about decision making in hospitals is that there is no single decision maker. Rather, decision making is a complex and often diffuse process involving multiple coalitions of key people, including physicians; administrators; trustees; and, increasingly, nurses. These coalitions exert different degrees of influence depending primarily on the topic. Typically, physicians exert the most influence over clinical matters, such as determining staff privileges, establishing practice protocols, reviewing quality of care, and determining patient admission and discharge. Executive-level administrators exert the most influence over hospital policy and planning activities particularly as they relate to the organization's external environment. Middle-level executives and department heads typically exert the most influence over matters related to daily staffing, budgeting, and procurement of supplies. The influence of trustees is primarily felt in the areas of long-run strategic planning and articulating the overall mission and direction of the hospital. Nurses are striving to become more involved in all of these areas. From this general description, it is possible-to highlight two general "models" of decision making in hospitals: the dual authority model and the shared authority model.
The Dual Authority Model
The dual authority model is best developed by Pauly and Redisch4 and Harris5 and was first described by Smith.6 In the Pauly/Redisch version the hospital is seen as a physicians' cooperative in which physicians' decisions largely determine the nature of hospital operations. The administration largely exists to provide the equipment, supplies, and facilities for physician use. Although two distinct lines of authority (administrative and clinical) are recognized, administrators seldom oppose physicians because the hospital's success and the administrator's own job security are closely tied to satisfying the demands of the physician staff
In the Harris version the administrative and medical split is conceptualized as two different "firms." The medical staff constitutes a "demand division" and the administration a ''supply division." Each division has its own managers, decision-making strategies, operating rules, and policies. Third-party payers recognize this separation in the form of separate payment policies for ambulatory care versus inpatient care. In brief, although hospitals and physicians are in fact involved in a joint production process, they are largely organized as separate entities; therein lies much of the difficulty in hospital decision making as it pertains to the allocation of scarce resources. Until recently, the "expert" power of the physician as legitimated by the state has dominated the decision-making process over the ''legitimate" power (i.e., formal position authority) of the administration. Furthermore, physicians control both their own and the hospital's inputs. As Harris notes:
Doctors are in a position to deem all sorts of demands as necessary for their patients. This is not the same thing as saying doctors order useless tests to satisfy some ulterior motives. Additional demands for inputs above the hypothetical scientific minimum are going to be regarded by doctors as improvements in quality.7
The issues suggested by the dual authority model of decision making are more complex for voluntary hospitals than for investor-owned hospitals. If one assumes that the goals of investor-owned hospitals are somewhat more homogeneous and targeted than are the goals of voluntary hospitals, the interests of physicians and the hospital may be more closely aligned. In contrast, voluntary hospitals may pursue a variety of community objectives, not all of which may contribute to financial viability and which may in fact detract from or even compete with physician interests. But as cost containment pressures continue, voluntary and investor-owned hospitals are becoming more alike in their orientation to financial viability. In single hospital communities, this may lead to further hospital competition with the medical staff. In multiple hospital communities where physicians have alternatives for admitting patients, hospitals are more likely to pursue initiatives that will complement rather than compete with staff interests.
The Shared Authority Model
The shared authority model is the product of recent developments. Briefly stated, it involves more conjoint8 or shared decision-making power between administrators and physicians and increased integration of clinical and administrative information. This model has emerged as a result of legal, economic, and societal forces. From a legal perspective, the Darling decision9 in 1965 established the hospital's ultimate legal responsibility for the quality of care. This responsibility can be delegated to the medical staff, but the final accountability resides with the hospital and its governing board. Although subsequent cases have modified and refined this landmark ruling, it has resulted in a fundamental change in the behavior of hospital administrators and trustees toward physicians in regard to establishing institutional accountability for physician behavior. It has provided administrators and trustees with a degree of legal clout.
The economic forces are twofold. First is the general concern about the inflationary economy, which has made it more costly for many organizations to function. Second, and more specifically, has been the concern over the continued above-average increases in the cost of medical care and hospital services in particular. This has led to a number of regulatory cost containment initiatives, including health systems agencies (HSAs); the PSROs; and, in a number of states, hospital rate review commissions. In addition, some states have experimented with hospital reimbursement based on comparable diagnostic case mix. It is beyond the purview of this paper to address the efficacy of these approaches to cost containment, but there is no question that hospitals have been operating in a environment of increasingly constrained resources, particularly over the past five years. From the perspective of hospital decision making, the most important consequence has been that administrators have gained power and influence in their negotiations with physicians to contain costs. Administrators may not agree with the regulations, but they can use them as an "external scapegoat" for promoting more efficient decision making by physicians in the use of hospital resources. In brief, hospitals and hospital administrators have been provided with greater economic clout.
The societal factors are complex but involve three primary considerations: (1) the demythification of the professions, including medicine; (2) the development of lifestyle alternatives emphasizing disease prevention, health promotion, and self-care; and (3) the rise of professionally trained health care managers. As access to higher education, particularly graduate education, has increased, some of the idealized self-images of the professions have been exposed to wider scrutiny. Furthermore, as society's problems have become more complex and intractable, the limitations of the professions to deal with them have become more obvious. Medicine has become a part of this process. Although still among the highest-rated professions, it no longer enjoys the same unquestioned respect and trust that it did 20 to 30 years ago. This is particularly true in areas outside its own domain of technical competence.
Even within medicine's domain of competence or its "functional specificity," 10 more people are recognizing its limitations.11 It is becoming increasingly recognized that good health is more strongly associated with genetics; environment; and lifestyle factors of diet, exercise, and management of stress than with the provision of medical services. Although clearly there are many exceptions (e.g., certain immunizations and some surgical procedures and drugs that promote both the quality and length of life), many Americans no longer see as close an association between good medical care and a healthy life as was true in the past. The above two events, the demythification of the medical profession and the development of alternative approaches to a healthy life, have created a new social context within which hospitals and physicians must operate. Both are subject to intense public scrutiny and an increased degree of "healthy skepticism" regarding their ability to provide services in a cost-effective fashion. In brief, a societal incentive has been provided to hospitals and physicians to work more cooperatively in meeting the changing needs and expectations of a more sophisticated and discriminating public.
To the above may be added the increase in the number of professionally trained health care managers. With greater training in financial management, quantitative methods, organizational behavior, marketing, and interpersonal relations, these managers have gained increased respect and trust from both hospital trustees and physicians. Seeing the need for increased clinical input into hospital decision making, these managers may also feel less threatened by such involvement and may be more willing to work with physicians in exerting joint leadership.
The legal clout, economic clout, and societal incentive described above are altering the relative balance of power between hospitals and physicians. It is no longer in the physician's economic interest to stand aloof from the process, and the hospital stands to gain by bringing resources more under the control of the organization—although at the "price" of greater physician involvement in hospital-wide decision making.
Strain Among Decision Makers and Between the Two Models
There are inherent strains between the needs of organizations and the needs of the professionals associated with them. These strains particularly affect hospital/physician relationships and the two models of decision making described above. Some of the more important strains are summarized in Table 4 and briefly noted below.
First, organizations have a high need for predictability in order to achieve their goals. In contrast, professionals have a high need for freedom to operate in the face of uncertainty. This is most widely recognized in the "exceptional cases" syndrome whereby health care professionals, physicians in particular, can assert that a given case is an "emergency" and thereby set aside the usual rules and regulations.
The organization also has a high need for goal commitment, particularly in regard to survival and effectiveness. Professionals, on the other hand, have a high need for professional goal commitment, which is less widely focused than organizational goals and tends to be centered more on individual patient treatment.
Organizations also have a high need for coordination and integration across tasks, services, and departments. In contrast, professionals have a high need for freedom to function within specialized interests. As Weisbord notes: "In medicine, professionals believe in their bones that procedures and organizational needs for ... survival will be inimical to theirs."12
Organizations have a high need for control and feedback, particularly concerning their public accountability. In contrast, professionals have a high need for individual accountability to patients and to professional peers.
Finally, organizations have a relatively high need for specialization to accomplish tasks. Professionals also have a high need for specialization but not necessarily in a manner compatible with the needs of the organization.
Overall, the organization's needs are largely macro in nature, reflecting the overall goals of the organization and the relationship of the organization to its larger environment. At the same time the organization's needs are primarily local in the sense that the commitment is to the organization, with professionals viewed as a vehicle for achievement of the organization's goals. In contrast, health care professionals are largely concerned with micro issues centered on individual patient care but with a cosmopolitan orientation characterized by a commitment to professional growth in the development of one's speciality. In brief, the organization is seen as the vehicle for the achievement of professional goals.
These are some of the fundamental differences that must be taken into account and managed whether one adopts a dual authority or shared authority decision-making model. In general, the above differences tend to reinforce the dual authority model and make it more difficult to bring about a shared model.
Types of Physician Decision-Making Involvement
Decision-making involvement takes two primary forms: formal and informal. The principal modes of formal physician involvement in hospital decision making are participation in meetings of the board of trustees and in the committee structure of the board, the administration, and the medical staff itself and in hospital/physician compensation arrangements whereby the physician is economically tied to the hospital's welfare.
The primary methods of informal involvement include interaction among administrators, trustees, medical staff members, and nurses along with informal ad hoc group discussion of issues as they arise. In general, the degree of formalization of the decision-making process increases with hospital size and complexity, although informal elements are always present. Also, in general, routine decisions such as changing inventory levels or adding a new staff member are made by individuals in the appropriate position or processed through the appropriate formal committee. Nonroutine decisions such as adding or dropping a major program usually are first discussed in informal ad hoc discussion groups, involving those with the most at stake. Only after some closure or at least clarification of the issue has been obtained will it be brought before appropriate committees for further discussion and a decision. In many cases the decision will have been made already, and the committee will simply rubber stamp it. In these nonroutine decisions it is often difficult to identify a single, clear-cut decision maker, and, indeed, the decisions themselves may not be clearly identifiable acts.13
Some systematic descriptive information exists on the degree of physician participation in hospital governing bodies and committees and on the percentage of hospital-compensated physicians. These data indicate that 42 percent of hospitals have one or more active staff physicians as voting members of their governing boards.14 Twenty-six percent of hospitals have physicians as members of the executive committee of the governing board, the group that usually conducts much of the board's business. The percentage of board members who are physicians is generally not related to bed size nor teaching status but is strongly related to ownership. Specifically, between 52 and 64 percent of for-profit hospital board members are physicians compared with approximately 11 to 26 percent for voluntary hospitals.15 Approximately 60 percent of for-profit hospitals have boards on which physicians are in the majority.16 At the same time, for-profit hospitals have relatively little physician involvement in committees other than board activities. This suggests that in for-profit hospitals physician involvement in decision making is centered primarily in the governance activities of the institution rather than in the committee structure per se. 17 Voluntary hospitals exhibit an opposite pattern, having greater physician participation in committees but less participation in governing board activities.
It is important to note, however, that physician involvement in hospital governing board activities says nothing about the degree of influence that governing boards exert over hospital policy and operation. In this regard there may be as much or more variability among investor-owned hospitals and among voluntary hospitals than between the two types. The Hospital Corporation of America (HCA), for example, operates on a strongly decentralized basis in which local hospital governing boards maintain some degree of discretion and influence, although accountability remains centralized. In contrast, Humana, Inc., operates on a highly centralized basis with more operating decisions made at the corporate office level and less autonomy provided to individual hospitals. The relative influence of hospital governing boards in investor-owned hospitals, freestanding voluntary hospitals, and voluntary multi-unit systems is an important issue for further investigation. For example, it is commonly believed that the influence of individual hospital boards is diminished in multi-unit systems, whether investor-owned or voluntary. But no systematic information is available to indicate the extent to which this is true or in what specific areas or types of decision making such differences may exist.
Overall, hospitals have approximately 4 medical staff committees per 100 beds.18 Two key committees are the joint conference committee, made up of trustee, hospital administration, and medical staff leaders, and the medical staff executive committee itself. Although all accreditated hospitals are required to have these two committees, their actual influence and practice varies widely. Other common committees are medical audit, utilization review, credentials, and the infection committee. The average number of committee members is 6, and the committees meet an average of 11 times per year. Approximately one-third of the medical staff committees have a nonphysician, usually an administrator or a nurse, with voting representation. For 58 percent of the committees the members are appointed either by the medical staff president, the hospital administrator, or by both acting jointly, rather than being elected by the staff.
In regard to physician compensation arrangements, nationally 25 percent of active staff physicians have some type of hospital financial arrangement, either part time or full time.19 Twenty-eight percent of department chiefs are on contract. Of all active staff with a contract, 23 percent are salaried. Arrangements whereby physicians are compensated by hospitals are more often found in teaching hospitals than in nonteaching hospitals.20 They also are more common in for-profit hospitals than in voluntary hospitals.21
Systematic longitudinal data are not available, but a general reading of the literature and conversations with hospital administrators and medical staffs suggest that physician involvement in governing board activities, participation in committees, and hospital-based compensation arrangements is growing. For example, over the past five years a number of hospitals have added cost containment committees, medical equipment purchase committees, and strategic long-range planning committees, all with physician participation. Thus, there appears to be a growing trend toward the shared authority model of decision making described earlier or at least deliberate attempts to blur the clear demarcation suggested by the dual authority model. Some of the effects of these changes on the cost and quality of patient care are examined below.
Hospital/Physician Decision Making and the Cost and Quality of Care
The issue of hospital/physician decision making is important primarily as it affects the delivery of patient care services. The relevant question is whether certain patterns of decision making are associated with improvements in the cost-effectiveness of the care delivered. Present research does not provide a clear-cut answer in terms of cause and effect, but the majority of the existing evidence suggests consistent associations between greater physician involvement in hospital decision making and lower costs. Existing research also suggests consistent associations between greater physician participation and higher quality of care. There is little evidence that costs can be contained only at the expense of lowering the quality of care. If anything, the evidence suggests that efforts to contain costs can be associated with improvements in the quality of care.
It is important to note that the research on the relationship between physician involvement in hospital decision making and the cost and quality of care has almost all been conducted in voluntary hospitals. Thus, little is known about this relationship in for-profit hospitals. This is another area for future research.
Evidence Regarding Costs
A number of studies have examined the relationship between various aspects of physician involvement in hospital decision making and cost of care.22 These studies generally indicate that the more aware physicians are of the organization's performance and the greater the number of scheduled meetings between such key clinical and patient care departments as radiology, laboratory, and nursing service, the lower the costs will be in specific medical support departments. Some evidence also suggests that for-profit hospitals have a higher ratio of nurses and physicians to support personnel, which in turn is more strongly associated with occupancy rates in for-profit hospitals than in not-for-profit hospitals.23 This may be due to the stronger economic orientation of the for-profit hospital, although in the current climate of economic constraint, not-for-profit hospitals also have a high need for surplus revenues. Thus, differences in economic orientation of for-profit versus not-for-profit hospitals may be narrowing.
The percentage of hospital-based physicians on contract also has been found to be positively associated with lower costs per admission, and physician presence on the executive committee of the governing board also is associated with lower costs per admission.24
Evidence Regarding Quality
A number of investigators have examined how the relationship between physicians and hospitals may affect the quality of patient care.25 In general, these studies suggest that greater physician participation in hospital decision making is positively associated with higher quality of care, as measured by such indicators as severity-adjusted death rates and postsurgical complication rates. There is also evidence that the greater the hospital administrators' ability to influence decisions within their domain, the higher the quality of care.26 Others have found positive relationships between quality of care and more highly structured medical staffs, as measured by appointment procedures, number of control committees, and percentage of physicians on contract.27 Morlock et al. also found evidence of a strong relationship between hospital trustee involvement in hospital decision making and the quality of care.28 In their study, hospitals with influential trustees were much more likely to have medical staff committees that met frequently and were more likely to produce frequent internal monitoring reports on quality of care statistics.
Evidence Regarding Possible Trade-Offs Between Cost and Quality
A major issue in physician/hospital decision making is the extent to which control of costs or improved efficiency can be achieved only at the expense of the quality of care. Most of the studies to date, however, suggest that efforts at containing costs are positively associated with quality. For example, a study of Chicago-area hospitals found that the more efficient hospitals, as measured by lower costs and lower man-hours per standardized unit of output, also provided higher-quality care, as evaluated by outside experts and as indicated by accreditation and severity-adjusted death rates.29 A study of hospitals in Massachusetts revealed that higher cost per case was associated with higher medical/surgical death rates, even when differences in case mix were taken into account.30 Other studies have generally found similar results.31 However, Flood et al. found that hospitals that provide a greater number of certain specific medical services that increase cost also had better than expected patient care outcomes.32 In this study the relationship between overall cost and measures of quality of care was not examined.
It is important to note that the above results are preliminary and suggestive at best, and they must be viewed with caution. Nonetheless, existing evidence offers little support for the argument or expectation that efficiency or cost containment goals are inherently incompatible with effectiveness or quality of care. It may be that greater physician involvement in hospital-wide administrative decision making facilitates cost containment decisions that protect or even enhance the quality of care provided. For example, changes to improve the turnaround time for laboratory tests not only improve hospital efficiency but may also improve quality of care by expediting the physician's diagnostic and treatment plans for the patient. Clearly, this is a major area for future research and public policy development. The effects of physician involvement in hospital-wide decision making on the overall use of hospital services is another important area for further investigation.
Future Issues
It should be evident from the above discussion that physician involvement in hospital decision making is in flux. As indicated, this is primarily due to changes in the external environment of health care delivery, which is causing physicians and hospitals to view themselves and each other in a different light. As a clue to the future it is useful to consider the changing context of both clinical decision making and institutional decision making. The possible demise of the traditional voluntary medical staff organization can be foreseen. It then becomes possible to consider the factors that either promote or constrain the movement toward more shared, collaborative decision-making models.
The Changing Context of Clinical Decision Making
Pellegrino has commented that:
The process of making clinical decisions is the balance wheel of hospital operation. It is central to all the patient-oriented functions of the hospital, and it has remote effects on all major elements of hospital organization—the patient, the health care professional, administrators, trustees, and the community. It is also the process least accessible to organizational control, the most in need of freedom, and yet the most potent of hospital processes for good and evil. The clinical decision is the most zealously guarded of the physician's prerogatives and at the same time the most in need of some kind of surveillance for individual and public good. It is, moreover, the most difficult process to evaluate in a definitive way.33
Five factors are redefining the context of clinical decision making: (1) the realization that resources are scarce—a ''logic of scarcity,'' (2) the continued impact of new technology, (3) changes in the mix of diseases being seen, (4) the increased institutionalization of all aspects of medical care, and (5) the effects of the consumer movement.
The concern over the cost of health care has resulted in a logic of scarcity that is beginning to permeate medical practice. There exists a subtle and still-developing change from the norm of "doing everything possible for the patient at all costs" to one of "doing only those things that might reasonably yield positive outcomes" and choosing the most cost-effective ways of doing those procedures. In the extreme this is resulting in the use of cost-benefit assessments in making decisions to treat some patients and not others. This is a profound and very important change. Never before has such a logic been a part of the "micro-level" of the health care system, the level of individual clinical decision making.
Continued advances in technology require continual rethinking of diagnostic and treatment protocols and clinical decision-making rules. This increases the rate of change and uncertainty, which in turn leads to greater specialization of function and greater competition among specialties. One example is the recent dispute among pathologists, radiologists, and internists over developments in nuclear medicine. Specifically, pathologists claim they have the facilities, space, and personnel to handle large-scale procedures; radiologists maintain they have the techniques; and internists, of course, note that they have the patients. A partial solution appears to have been worked out in the development of a conjoint board that is sponsored by all three specialties and that allows access to certification in nuclear medicine from each of them.
There have also been appreciable changes in the mix of diseases being seen—specifically in the chronic, complex conditions associated with aging. One implication of this change is that teams of different kinds of specialists and providers are needed to provide effective care. This further complicates the clinical decision-making process and raises a number of issues involving who should be the team leader and who should assume various roles and responsibilities.
As previously noted, medical care is increasingly an organizational process, subject to organizational forms of social control. The Darling decision, which held hospitals and their governing boards ultimately responsible for quality of care, helped give rise to PSROs and related institutionalized forms of review.
Finally, there is continued interest by the public in having more control over their own lives, and, as previously noted, this has affected the health care professions. The public has a desire to know more and to be given more choices, including the choice not to seek or comply with medical advice. Manifestations are emerging both in collective bodies such as health planning agencies and at the level of the individual provider-patient relationship. As such, they have affected clinical decision making, if only as a sensitizing factor that further complicates the decision-making process.
The effect of these five factors has been to transform the context in which clinical decisions are made. In brief, such decisions are no longer within the exclusive domain of the medical profession; the boundaries have become more permeable, allowing participation by other providers, health care organizations, regulatory groups, consumers, and others. The issue is whether the continued prevalence of dual authority decision-making structures or the continuing emergence of shared decision-making authority structures provides a better forum for dealing with the increased complexity and diffuseness of clinical decision making.
The Changing Context of Institutional Decision Making
Not only are hospitals under increased public scrutiny because of the continuing rise in costs, but it also seems likely that hospitals will remain under such scrutiny permanently. This is not only because of the continued concern regarding the cost-effectiveness of patient care but also because hospitals, individually and collectively, have taken on more characteristics of industrial enterprises central to the American economy. Many individual hospitals are joining multi-unit systems to gain greater economic and political clout. Approximately 26 percent of all hospitals belong to a multi-unit system now, and estimates suggest that close to 80 percent may belong to such systems by 1990.34 Even among individual hospitals there has been growth in professional managerial staff specialists, marketing specialists, long-range planning departments, and health services research units.
Regulation of capital and operating expenses plus an inflationary economy have forced hospitals to compete more with each other for patients, physicians, and nurses. In many areas of the country, voluntary hospitals are competing directly with investor-owned hospitals, and teaching hospitals are competing with nonteaching hospitals. The result is that voluntary and investor-owned hospitals are becoming more alike, ironically as a result of trying to differentiate their services in an attempt to find new markets for growth. Thus, some voluntary hospitals are entering into management contract relationships with other voluntary hospitals and are forming systems that are similar to those of investor-owned hospitals, and some investor-owned hospitals are beginning to offer outreach and satellite services similar to those offered by voluntary hospitals. Teaching hospitals are becoming more like their community hospital counterparts in offering more general primary care services and community outreach services, and community hospitals are striving to expand their markets by adding the more sophisticated technology found in teaching hospitals.
American hospitals are no longer a cottage industry; they are part of an industry that is becoming more highly concentrated, more competitive, and more heavily interdependent with other organizations. It is also an industry that is extremely vulnerable to economic, regulatory, and technological changes. As such, decision making, particularly at the upper policymaking levels of the organization, has become a very complex and difficult process. The number of inspirational decisions relative to computational decisions has increased. There is an increased need to turn more of these inspirational decisions into judgmental or compromise decisions.
There also is a greater need for clinical participation in the administrative decision-making process and consideration of more administrative and economic matters in the clinical decision-making process. The following question may be raised: Is the current relationship of physicians to hospitals, in the form of the voluntary medical staff, able to meet the challenge of the new decision-making environment? In brief, is the voluntary medical staff organization structure rapidly becoming an anachronism?
The Demise of the Voluntary Medical Staff
Fundamental changes in the structure of medical staff organization may be taking place already. A growing number of physicians are affiliating with hospitals as a cost-effective way of starting practices, a growing number of speciality-trained physicians are contracting with one or more hospitals to deliver secondary and tertiary care services, and a growing number of hospital medical staffs are entering into HMO arrangements of various forms.35 As the predicted physician surplus materializes over the next decade, competition among physicians will grow, and many will look to the above kinds of arrangements to gain competitive advantages. But what effect will these trends have on physician/hospital decision-making relationships? Although it is safe to say that the dual authority model will continue to prevail in most settings, it is likely that shifts toward more shared models will become more prevalent, depending on a number of factors, highlighted below, that may facilitate or constrain such a movement.
Factors Promoting or Impeding Shared Decision-Making Models
Expectations of more shared decision making between physicians and hospitals can be based on several arguments. The first is that the physician surplus will make physicians more dependent on hospitals for privileges and services to build and maintain their practices; thus, their economic well-being will become more closely identified with that of the hospital. This will provide a stimulus for more joint physician/hospital involvement in decision making. Second, as regulation (at any governmental level) continues, physicians and hospitals may perceive increased incentives to unite against the "common enemy." Consistent with the "capture" theory of regulation (whereby the industry itself desires the regulation so as to protect its own interest), physicians and hospitals will work together to make sure their mutual interests are protected. Hospital reimbursement based on case mix also may require more collaborative decision making as such reimbursement requires administrative and cost data to be integrated with clinical data.
Third, as physicians become more closely aligned to hospitals, they may demand greater participation in hospital-wide decision making than they currently have through traditional medical staff organization channels. In brief, they may seek to have greater influence with an organization that is gaining greater importance in their professional lives.
Finally, shared decision-making models may be facilitated by more sophisticated and enlightened physicians and professionally trained hospital administrators. More physicians are being exposed to the importance of cost-effective medical care and associated cost-effectiveness and cost-benefit methodologies. Some, such as graduates of the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation's Clinical Scholars Program, have received broad exposure to health services and health policy issues. Thus, there may be emerging a new cadre of medical leadership with a broader understanding of the hospital both as an economic and a social institution, which overrides the notion of the hospital as simply the "doctor's workshop." As noted by the Hospital Association of Pennsylvania:
The hospital-medical staff relationship is currently the weakest link in the hospital corporate management structure. It is this weakness, together with the rising cost issue, which will force a new relationship between physicians and hospitals in the very near future.
Joint decision-making involving medical staffs will need to be developed to gain their participation in an acceptance of change in institutional procedures.36
On the other hand, several factors could impede the development of shared decision-making models. First, increased physician competition, resulting from the developing surplus of physicians, could result in more physicians offering services in direct competition with hospitals. Emerging examples include emergency care, sports medicine, and health promotion. Under increasing competition, primary care physicians in particular may seek to develop special services. Whether they choose to compete directly with hospitals will depend on a number of local market factors and customs, including the power of local hospitals, the demographic composition of the community, and the organization of the medical practice community itself. For example, it would be difficult for a new solo practitioner to compete with a hospital, but it would be easier if new physicians could join well-established group practices and develop new programs and services from that base.
A second factor that may cause physicians to keep an arm's-length relationship with hospitals is the physician's desire to escape the regulation and reimbursement controls imposed on hospitals. If physicians see little opportunity to change the regulatory or payment climate by working with hospitals, some will move to distance themselves from its consequences by becoming as autonomous as possible. This will have essentially the same effect as noted above in regard to competition, i.e., the provision of more services in the physician's offices. For such services as radiology and pathology this has already resulted in the purchase of more sophisticated equipment for physician's offices (e.g., computed tomographic scanners), as opposed to locating them in the hospital.
A third deterrent to the development of more shared decision-making models may be the unwillingness of hospital administrators to open up the decision-making process to physicians. This is likely to be a significant issue in many areas and is understandable given the historical evolution of administrator-physician relationships in U.S. hospitals. Essentially, administrators have used informal and persuasive skills (in addition to the legitimate authority derived from their positions) to gain influence over medical staffs. In particular, they have used their role as intermediary between the medical staff and the board of trustees to control communication and information flow and thus to keep some control over the medical staff's influence on the board. The idea of involving physicians more systematically in hospital-wide policymaking presents a major challenge for administrators and physicians alike.
Summary
This paper has attempted to capture some of the complexity and dynamics of changing physician/hospital decision-making relationships. A typology and a number of examples of physician/hospital decision making were developed to provide a framework for considering current developments. Some differences were suggested in decision-making strategies by hospital ownership and whether the hospital belonged to a multi-unit system. Two major models of physician/hospital relationships were described—the dual authority model and the shared authority model. The implications of each of these along with the forces influencing their continued development were examined. Evidence regarding the association of more shared decision-making models and the cost and quality of care was summarized. A number of issues pertaining to the changing context of clinical and institutional decision making were presented, suggesting that some fundamental changes may take place in the structure of hospital medical staffs.
These points have a number of possible implications for for-profit hospitals. First, they are likely to continue to be somewhat more selective than voluntary hospitals in their choice of services to offer the community. Specifically, they will tend to offer services that enhance the return on the overall portfolio or mix of services provided. Because of the greater involvement of physicians in hospital governance, for-profit hospitals may be more reluctant to compete directly with their medical staffs and more likely to offer services that are complementary to rather than substitutable for physician services in the community.
Second, for-profit hospitals, particularly those owned by investor-owned chains, may be better able than voluntary hospitals to deal with "compromise" or "judgmental" decisions. This is because they have a more clearly defined and homogenous group of constituents (stockholders) and generally more overall centralized direction from the corporate headquarters office. As a result, preferences regarding desired outcomes may be more clear. Investor-owned hospitals may, therefore, be more able to make rapid adjustment to external changes (e.g., changes in third-party reimbursement or changes in competition) than most voluntary hospitals can.
Third, because the interests of physicians and the hospital may be more closely aligned in for-profit hospitals, the dual authority model of decision making is less problematic. Perhaps the lesser degree of physician involvement in daily committee work that characterizes for-profit hospitals reflects a higher degree of agreement on a more homogenous and targeted set of goals and greater physician involvement in the governance process. In contrast, voluntary hospitals deal with the issues created by the dual authority model through a rather elaborate system of committees attempting to achieve increased physician participation and involvement. Although both types of hospitals may be shifting toward a more shared authority model, investor-owned hospitals may be able to make the adjustment more quickly and easily because of the greater degree of agreement on overall goals and the history of physician involvement in decision making at the governance level of the organization.
But it is also important to note that the above differences and their implications may be attenuated by some growing similarities between for-profit and voluntary hospitals in their economic orientations. Under pressures for cost containment, plus increased competition, voluntary hospitals have had to give more concerted thought both-to their short-run operational needs and to longer-run capital formation requirements. A number of voluntary hospitals have corporately reorganized, in many instances creating for-profit subsidiaries to expand the hospital's sources of revenue. Some of the above differences may also be attenuated by the continued growth of multi-unit systems among not-for-profit hospitals. Through their corporate office expertise and structure, such systems may be able to offer the same kinds of advantages as the investor-owned systems. In brief, although important differences still exist between the mission, philosophy, structure, and decision making of for-profit and not-for-profit hospitals, forces are currently in motion that over time may diminish some of these differences.
References and Notes
Footnotes
- *
It is recognized that there are also important differences between teaching and non-teaching hospitals, but the primary focus of this paper is on ownership and system versus nonsystem differences.
- A Typology of Hospital Decision Making
- Convergence versus Divergence of Interests
- The Decision Makers
- Strain Among Decision Makers and Between the Two Models
- Types of Physician Decision-Making Involvement
- Hospital/Physician Decision Making and the Cost and Quality of Care
- Future Issues
- Summary
- References and Notes
- Physician Involvement in Hospital Decision Making - The New Health Care for Prof...Physician Involvement in Hospital Decision Making - The New Health Care for Profit
- Marfan Syndrome/Loeys-Dietz Syndrome/Familial Thoracic Aortic Aneurysms and Diss...Marfan Syndrome/Loeys-Dietz Syndrome/Familial Thoracic Aortic Aneurysms and DissectionsMedGen
- CN229799[conceptid] (1)MedGen
- AnticoagulantsAnticoagulantsAgents that prevent BLOOD CLOTTING.<br/>MeSH
Your browsing activity is empty.
Activity recording is turned off.
See more...